HARVARD LAW SCHOOL
Intellectual Property Law and the
Boundaries of the Firm
Gideon Parchomovsky
June 2004
This paper can be downloaded without charge from the
Social Science Research. Network Paper Collection at
John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business
Discussion Paper No. 480
UNIVERSITY OF PENNSYLVANIA LAW SCHOOL
Law and Economics Research Paper Series
Research Paper No. 04-19
http://ssrn.com/abstract=559195
http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/
Oren Bar-Gill
JEL Classification: D23, K11, L22.
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW AND THE BOUNDARIES OF THE FIRM
Oren Bar-Gill
*
and Gideon Parchomovsky
**
Abstract
Arrow’s disclosure paradox implies that information that is not afforded legal protection
cannot be bought or sold on the market. This paper emphasizes the important relationship
between the paradox of disclosure and the boundaries of the firm question. Only legally
protected inventions, i.e., patented inventions, may be traded; pre-patent stages of the
innovation process may not. Consequently, by force of law, rather than by the guidance
of economic principle, pre-patent innovation must be carried out within the boundaries of
a single firm.
Keywords: Boundaries of the firm, disclosure paradox, intellectual property law.
*
Harvard University, the Society of Fellows, and Harvard Law School, the John M. Olin Center for Law,
Economics and Business.
**
University of Pennsylvania Law School.
This paper greatly benefited from comments and criticisms by Ian Ayres, Lucian Bebchuk, Omri
Ben-Shahar, Yochai Benkler, James Bessen, Chaim Fershtman, Zohar Goshen, Oliver Hart, Josh Lerner,
Robert Merges, Eric Posner, Ariel Porat, Mark Ramseyer, Edward Rock, Chris Sanchirico, Peter
Siegelman, Omri Yadlin and seminar participants at Boston University and Penn. We thank Efrat Procaccia
for excellent research assistance. Finally, we thank the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and
Business at Harvard Law School and the William F. Milton Fund of Harvard University for generous
financial support.
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW AND THE BOUNDARIES OF THE FIRM
Oren Bar-Gill
*
and Gideon Parchomovsky
**
? 2004 Oren Bar-Gill and Gideon Parchomovsky. All rights reserved.
1. Introduction
Innovation is crucial in technology intensive markets. For many firms inventions
are a critical factor of production. Examples of downstream firms purchasing or licensing
technology from upstream innovators are common (see, e.g., Arora et al., 2001). Indeed,
both Transaction Costs Economics (TCE) and the Property Rights Theory (PRT) suggest
that in many cases, efficiency requires that the inventive process—from the conception of
an idea through its development and ultimate commercialization—be divided among
several firms (Williamson, 1975; Aghion and Tirole, 1994; Arora et al., 2001; Arora and
Merges, 2004).
The question thus becomes which stages of the inventive process should be
integrated in a single firm and which should be divided among different firms and traded
on the market? We argue that the theoretic investigation of the optimal boundary between
firm and market cannot be carried out in a legal vacuum. Ideally, only the economic
considerations identified by TCE and PRT should affect the “make or buy” decision. In
practice, however, law imposes an important constraint on the economic balance between
firms and markets.
Critically, the law defines which stages of the inventive process are amenable to
market trading. As Arrow (1962) recognized, information that is not afforded legal
protection cannot be bought or sold on the market. Absent legal protection, the
information holder is in a bind: in order to sell the information, she must disclose it to the
potential buyer, but once she does, she has nothing left to sell. This paper emphasizes the
important relationship between Arrow’s paradox of disclosure and the question of the
boundaries of information intensive firms. Only legally protected inventions, i.e.,
patented inventions, may be traded; pre-patent stages of the innovation process may not.
Consequently, by force of law, rather than by the guidance of economic principle, pre-
patent innovation must be carried out within the boundaries of a single firm.
Intellectual property law is therefore an important factor influencing the boundary
between the firm and the market. When it is more difficult to obtain a patent more
innovative activity must be integrated within a single firm (or be forgone altogether).
*
Harvard University, the Society of Fellows, and Harvard Law School, the John M. Olin Center for Law,
Economics and Business.
**
University of Pennsylvania Law School.
This paper greatly benefited from comments and criticisms by Ian Ayres, Lucian Bebchuk, Omri
Ben-Shahar, Yochai Benkler, James Bessen, Chaim Fershtman, Zohar Goshen, Oliver Hart, Josh Lerner,
Robert Merges, Eric Posner, Ariel Porat, Mark Ramseyer, Edward Rock, Chris Sanchirico, Peter
Siegelman, Omri Yadlin and seminar participants at Boston University and Penn. We thank Efrat Procaccia
for excellent research assistance. Finally, we thank the John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and
Business at Harvard Law School and the William F. Milton Fund of Harvard University for generous
financial support.
1
Conversely, when the legal requirements of patentability are relaxed, as they have been in
recent years, a shift of activity from firms to the market should be expected. Trade secret
law and the legal treatment of covenants not to compete similarly affect firm boundaries
by determining the allocation of entitlements between firms and employees.
The implications of innovation for the make-or-buy decision have been
highlighted by Williamson (1975), Teece (1986, 1988), and Aghion and Tirole (1994).
Previous work has also recognized the relevance of appropriability and intellectual
property law to various contractual, strategic and organizational questions in technology-
intensive industries. The importance of appropriability and the relationship between
appropriability and intellectual property rights was first emphasized by Teece (1986).
Arora et al. (2001) highlight the difficulty in contracting over tacit knowledge and know-
how (ch. 5), noting “the role of patents in facilitating transactions in technology.” (p. 262)
Gans and Stern (2003a) consider the implications of the disclosure paradox for an
entrepreneur’s choice of a commercialization strategy, recognizing the role of intellectual
property in solving the paradox. In a couple of related empirical studies, these authors
show how intellectual property rights and appropriability problems affect the timing of
cooperation/licensing (Gans and Stern, 2003b) as well as the choice of a start-up
innovator between competition or cooperation (i.e. contracting) with more established
firms (Gans et al., 2000). Another recent empirical study shows that technologies
developed by firms operating in countries with weak intellectual property rights are used
more internally (Zhao, 2003). Anton and Yao, in a series of papers, explore the
implications of and the strategic responses to the disclosure paradox, caused by imperfect
legal protection of pre-patent ideas (Anton and Yao, 1994, 2000, 2001, 2003a, 2003b; see
also Bhattacharya and Guriev, 2004).
Finally, Dan Burk and Ashish Arora and Robert Merges, in two recent
contributions, explicitly focus on the interrelations between intellectual property law and
the boundaries of the firm question. Burk (2004) focuses on the implications of the theory
of the firm for intellectual property law. While we focus on the reverse implications of
intellectual property law for the theory of the firm, Burk’s insights are clearly important
for our analysis. Arora and Merges (2004) show that stronger intellectual property rights
support smaller firms that specialize in the supply of technology inputs. The analysis in
Arora and Merges (2004) can be interpreted as proposing one way to minimize the costs
associated with the disclosure paradox—through intellectual property rights in
complementary assets (see also Merges, 2000; Arora et al., 2001). Our focus, on the other
hand, is on intellectual property rights in the core informational asset. More generally,
while the literature has focused on the strength of intellectual property rights, we focus on
the preconditions for the creation of legally enforceable intellectual property rights.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents a simple
model, formalizing the role of intellectual property law as a constraint on the optimal
level of vertical integration in technology-intensive industries. Section 3 draws the
broader implications of the model for the structure and organization of technology-
intensive industries, discussing firm size, the role of research universities, R&D alliances
and joint ventures, and R&D financing. Section 4 argues that intellectual property law
affects not only the feasibility of the market option but also the feasibility of the firm
option. Section 5 concludes.
2
2. Model
We formalize the effect of intellectual property law on the boundaries of the firm
question using a simple PRT model.
1
Consider an inventor (I) and a developer (D). An
innovation process combining the efforts of both I and D produces a value V(i,d), where i
denotes I’s investment and d denotes D’s investment. The value of I’s outside option is
, and the value of D’s outside option is . Assuming ,
the first-best investment levels are given by
)(iv
I
)(dv
D
)()(),( dvivdiV
DI
+>
didiV
di
??),(max
,
.
Non-verifiability of investments implies contractual incompleteness that restricts
the parties’ options to a choice between integration (Int) and non-integration (NInt).
Under the integration option, D owns the product of I’s effort.
2
Consequently, I does not
enjoy any of the value created by her efforts, and is motivated to invest only by the soft
incentives created within the integrated firm.
3
Let denote I’s investment under
integration. D’s investment under integration is given by:
ii
Int
?
=
ddiVd
d
Int
?= ),
?
(maxarg .
Total net payoffs under integration are: ( ) ( )
IntIntIntIntIntInt
didiVdi ??=Π ,,.
The second alternative is non-integration (NInt), whereby I retains control over
her invention, and can sell it to D ex post. The non-integration option, however, is not
always available. Given the disclosure paradox, the NInt option is feasible only if the law
recognizes the product of I’s efforts as intellectual property, thus affording it legal
protection. If such IP protection is granted, ex post the parties will negotiate a transfer of
the legal rights from I to D. Assuming Nash bargaining, the ex post surplus
is equally divided between the parties. Hence, I’s ex post payoff is )()(),( dvivdiV
DI
??
[ ])()(),()(),(
2
1
dvivdiVivdi
DIII
??+=π , and D’s ex post payoff is
[ ])()(),()(),(
2
1
dvivdiVdvdi
DIDD
??+=π . The investment levels are given by:
idii
I
i
NInt
?= ),(maxarg π and ddid
D
d
NInt
?= ),(maxarg π . We assume the existence
of a unique equilibrium ( )
NIntNInt
di , . Total net payoffs under integration are:
( ) ( )
NIntNIntNIntNIntNIntNInt
didiVdi ??=Π ,,.
We can now state the following:
Proposition: When ( ) ( )
IntIntNIntNInt
didi ,, Π>Π , if I’s invention is legally protected, then
non-integration will obtain, but if I’s invention is not legally protected, integration will
obtain.
1
The PRT framework employed in this section borrows from Hart (1995) and from Aghion and Tirole
(1994). A TCE model could readily be developed to capture the same effect.
2
Theoretically, the reverse form of integration, where I owns the combined product of both parties’ efforts,
is also possible. Following Aghion and Tirole (1994), we choose not to focus on this form of integration,
which can be ruled out if I is cash constrained.
3
These soft incentives include the possibility of promotion/demotion (or even dismissal),
increased/decreased salary and other monetary and non-monetary benefits and costs conferred by the
inventor’s managers and peers. See, e.g., Williamson (1975). If the value of the final output V is verifiable,
then I’s employment contract in the Int case can be made contingent on V, thus improving I’s incentives.
3
An integrated firm cannot replicate the “high-powered incentives” provided under
non-integration, hence (Williamson, 1985). Accordingly, the non-integration
option is more efficient when the marginal importance of I’s investment is large enough
relative to D’s investment (Grossman and Hart, 1986). But if the law does not protect the
product of I’s investment, the non-integration option is precluded by the disclosure
paradox, forcing the parties to integrate.
IntNInt
ii >
4
More generally, the Proposition implies that if I’s invention is not legally
protected integration will necessarily occur, and that such integration will be inefficient
when ( ) ( )
IntIntNIntNInt
didi ,, Π>Π . The welfare implications of this result depend on the
size of the set of cases where non-integration is superior to integration. Characterizing
this set of cases has been and remains the main task of the boundaries of the firm
literature. The welfare loss attributed to imperfect intellectual property rights would be
small, if the law would refuse to protect I’s invention only when integration is the optimal
organizational structure. Unfortunately, legal rules are not calibrated to the economic
factors that determine the relative efficiency of integration versus non-integration. In fact,
the legal distinction between protected and unprotected inventions is probably orthogonal
to the economic choice between integration and non-integration.
Finally, the Proposition assumes that the integration option is always feasible.
This assumption is not always valid. Specifically, when the law precludes the non-
integration option and the inefficiency of forced integration is sufficiently large, the
innovation project might be abandoned altogether, introducing yet another welfare cost.
5
3. Implications
The simple model developed in Section 2 has broad implications for the structure
and organization of technology-intensive industries:
1) Basic research in commercial firms: Significant R&D at the very fundamental level is
being done within commercial firms such as IBM and Motorola. While theory does not
preclude the efficiency of such integration, there is good reason to believe that basic
research should not generally be integrated with commercial enterprise. The absence of
legal protection for pre-patent innovation is arguably a contributing factor for the
integration of such innovation within firms that specialize in development and
commercialization.
2) Research universities: A major role of universities is to foster basic research at the pre-
patent stages. For present purposes, a research university is an organization, not unlike a
commercial firm, that can provide soft incentives for R&D activities that do not result in
a legally protected invention. In addition, public subsidization of basic research in
4
While straightforward non-integration and trade are precluded by the disclosure paradox, in some cases
the non-integration option cannot be completely ruled out. Even in the absence of legal protection of her
invention, the inventor may be able to extract some value from the developer. See Teece (1986), Anton and
Yao (1994, 2002), Arora (2001), Zucker et al. (2001), and Biais and Perotti (2003). Also, in certain
contexts innovators are driven by non-pecuniary motives and are thus more willing to share ideas across
firm boundaries. See Lessig (2001), and Benkler (2002).
5
Regarding the feasibility of the integration option see also Section 4 below.
4
universities can be understood as a response to imperfect intellectual property rights. If
the law does not protect an invention, then this invention may be developed within an
integrated firm, or when the inefficiency of the integration option is sufficiently large the
invention might not be developed at all. Public funding may be the only way—other than
extending the scope of intellectual property—to ensure the development of such
inventions.
3) R&D alliances: In the new, technology-intensive economy R&D alliances are an
increasingly common phenomenon. Given imperfect intellectual property rights, the
organizational structure of an alliance must respond to problems akin to those underlying
the disclosure paradox. Specifically, the two partner firms are faced with a choice
between a contract joint venture, where the object of the alliance becomes the subject of
an explicit contract, and an equity joint venture, where the two partner firms incorporate a
separate entity that will conduct R&D activities. When the law does not protect the stage
of the inventive process that is the subject of the alliance, the partner firms might be
forced to choose a less efficient equity structure.
6
4) R&D financing: The disclosure paradox that plagues the relationship between potential
sellers and buyers of pre-patent inventions might also prevent efficient external financing
of the pre-patent stages of the inventive process (see Aghion and Tirole, 1994). Excessive
integration to enable internal financing might follow. More generally the locus of
innovation might inefficiently shift to larger firms capable of internal financing.
4. Employee Mobility
As argued above, intellectual property law affects the viability of the market
option, thus influencing the boundary between firm and market. But the market option is
not the only organizational form affected by the law. The viability of the firm, as an
alternative to the market, also depends on the law’s willingness to protect intangible
assets.
Under the PRT, a firm is a collection of assets over which a manager enjoys
residual control rights. Specifically, the firm controls employees’ access to and use of its
assets (Hart, 1995). With traditional, tangible assets unauthorized use can be easily
prevented by restricting physical access to the asset. With intangible assets, however,
control of access to the asset is often meaningless. When an employee, through initial
access, acquires certain knowledge, denial of future access will not erase this knowledge.
Access control is thus powerless to prevent unauthorized use, specifically use by the
employee after she moves to another firm. If the law does not protect the intangible asset,
the firm loses all control over the asset; and, in essence, the knowledge ceases to be the
firm’s asset.
7
6
The implications of weak intellectual property rights for the organization of R&D alliances have been
previously recognized. See Oxley (1997, 1999), Anand and Khanna (2000), Sampson (2004), Majewski
and Williamson (2003).
7
In fact, legal protection is also a prerequisite for tangible assets. The firm’s ability to restrict physical
access to tangible assets relies on the law’s recognition of property rights in these assets.
5
Patent law provides one channel for protecting intangible assets. Kim and
Marschke (2001) argue that firms patent to reduce the incidence of employees leaving to
start or join rival firms (see also Merges, 1999). But not all intangible assets qualify for
patent protection, and some lack the minimal degree of verifiability necessary for patent
protection. The law provides alternative channels for controlling the use of intangible
assets by employees. Trade secret law is one such channel (Merges et al., 2003). Another
channel focuses on direct limitations on employee mobility, through the law governing
non-compete clauses. See Aghion and Tirole (1994), Gilson (1999), Baccara and Razin
(2002), Hellmann (2002) and Burk (2004).
The theory of the firm literature presumes the viability of both the market option
and the firm alternative, and proceeds to study the optimal choice between these two
options. The viability of both options, however, depends on the law’s willingness to
recognize property rights in intangibles. Sections 2 and 3 argued that without such
property rights innovation that should have ideally been mediated by the market would be
forced into the confines of a single firm. The present section suggested that even the firm
haven relies on some form of legal protection.
5. Conclusion
Intellectual property law directly affects the structure and organization of
technology-intensive industries by imposing an often binding constraint on the choice
between integration and non-integration. This characterization of legally determined
appropriability as a constraint on organizational choice provides a simple theoretical link
between the growing literature on the organization of innovation and the conventional
TCE and Property Rights theories of the firm.
The predictions of our model sit well with the empirical evidence on the
relationship between legal and organizational variations. Recently intellectual property
law has made it easier to obtain patent protection for embryonic inventions (see, e.g.,
Mazzoleni and Nelson, 1998). The increasing importance of small specialty R&D firms
(see, e.g., Arora and Merges, 2004), the increase in the number of university patents
(described, for example, in Arora et al., 2001, sec. 10.4), and the prevalence of non-
integration, non-equity research alliances and joint-ventures (see, e.g., Sampson, 2004)
can be at least partially explained by the relaxation of the legal patentability
requirements. Similarly, the growth of the venture capital industry arguably was
stimulated by the law’s increasing willingness to grant intellectual property rights to
small research start-ups—the archetypal user of venture capital funding. Looking
forward, our analysis, by identifying the different channels through which intellectual
property law affects the boundaries between firm and market, suggests a range of testable
predictions that we hope will motivate future empirical work.
6
References
Aghion, Philippe and Tirole, Jean (1994), “The Management of Innovation,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 109, 1185-1209.
Anand, Bharat N. and Khanna, Tarun (2000), “The Structure of Licensing Contracts,”
Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 103-135.
Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (1994), “Expropriation and Inventions: Appropriable
Rents in the Absence of Property Rights,” American Economic Review, 84, 190-
209.
Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2000), “Little Patents and Big Secrets: Managing
Intellectual Property,” mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.
Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2002), “The Sale of Ideas: Strategic Disclosure,
Property Rights, and Contracting,” forthcoming in Review of Economic Studies.
Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2003a), “Entrepreneurs and New Ideas,” mimeo,
University of Pennsylvania.
Anton, James J. and Yao, Dennis A. (2003b), “Attracting Skeptical Buyers,” mimeo,
University of Pennsylvania.
Arora, Ashish, Fosfuri, Andrea and Gambardella, Alfonso (2001), Markets for
Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate Strategy (MIT Press).
Arora, Ashish and Merges, Robert P. (2004), “Specialized Supply Firms, Property Rights
and Firm Boundaries,” Industrial and Corporate Change, 13, 451-475.
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1962), “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for
Invention,” in Richard R. Nelson (ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity,
609-625.
Baccara, Mariagiovanna and Razin, Ronny (2002), “From Thought to Practice:
Appropriation and Endogenous Market Structure with Imperfect Intellectual
Property Rights,” mimeo, Princeton University.
Benkler, Yochai (2002), “Coase’s Penguin, or, Linux and The Theory of the Firm,” Yale
Law Journal, 112, 369-446.
Bhattacharya, Sudipto, and Guriev, Sergei (2004), “Knowledge Disclosure, Patents, and
Optimal Organization of Research and Development,” mimeo, Princeton
University.
Biais, Bruno and Perotti, Enrico (2003), “Entrepreneurs and New Ideas,” mimeo,
Toulouse University.
Burk, Dan L. (2004), “Intellectual Property and the Firm,” University of Chicago Law
Review, 71, 3-20.
Gans, Joshua S., Hsu, David H., and Stern, Scott (2000), “When Does Start-Up
Innovation Spur the Gale of Creative Destruction?” NBER Working Paper No.
W7851.
Gans, Joshua S. and Stern, Scott (2003a), “The Product Market and the Market for
“Ideas”: Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs,” Research
Policy, 32, 333-350.
Gans, Joshua S. and Stern, Scott (2003b), “The Impact of Uncertain IP Rights on the
Market for Ideas: Evidence from Patent Grant Delays,” mimeo, Northwestern
University.
7
Gilson, Ronald J. (1999), “The Legal Infrastructure of High Technology Industrial
Districts: Silicon Valley, Route 128, and Covenants Not to Compete,” New York
University Law Review, 74, 575-629.
Grossman, Sanford and Hart, Oliver (1986), “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A
Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration,” Journal of Political Economy, 94, 691-
719.
Hart, Oliver (1995), Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure (Oxford University Press,
New York, NY).
Hellmann, Thomas (2002), “When Do Employees Become Entrepreneurs?” Research
Paper No. 1770, Stanford Business School.
Kim, J. and Marschke, G. (2001), “Labor Mobility of Scientists, Technological Diffusion,
and the Firm’s Patenting Decision,” mimeo, available at
http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=288580.
Lessig, Lawrence (2001), The Future of Ideas (Random House, New York).
Majewski, Suzanne E. and Williamson, Dean V. (2003), “Incomplete Contracting and the
Structure of R&D Agreements,” mimeo, Harvard University.
Mazzoleni, Roberto and Nelson, Richard R. (1998), “The Benefits and Costs of Strong
Patent Protection: A Contribution to the Current Debate,” Research Policy, 27, 273-
284.
Merges, Robert P. (1995), “Intellectual Property and the Costs of Commercial Exchange:
A Review Essay,” Michigan Law Review, 93, 1570-1615.
Merges, Robert P. (1999), “The Law and Economics of Employee Inventions,” 13
Harvard Journal of Law & Technology, 13, 1-54.
Merges, Robert P. (2000), “Property Rights as Contractual Safeguards,” mimeo, UC
Berkeley.
Merges, Robert P., Menell, Peter S. and Lemley, Mark (2003), Intellectual Property in
the New Technology Age (3
rd
ed., Aspen Law and Business, New York).
Oxley, Joanne E. (1997), “Appropriability Hazards and Governance in Strategic
Alliances: A Transaction Cost Approach,” 13 Journal of Law, Economics &
Organization 387-409.
Oxley, Joanne E. (1999), “Institutional Environment and the Mechanisms of Governance:
The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter-firm
Alliances,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38, 283-309.
Sampson, Rachelle C. (2004), “The Cost of Misaligned Governance in R&D Alliances,”
forthcoming in Journal of Law, Economics & Organization.
Teece, David (1986), “Profiting from Technological Innovation: Implications for
Integration, Collaboration, Licensing, and Public Policy,” Research Policy, 15, 285-
305.
Teece, David (1988), “Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm,” in Dosi, G. et
al. (eds.), Technical Change and Economic Theory 256-281 (Frances Pinter,
London, UK).
Williamson, Oliver (1975), Markets and Hierarchies (Free Press, New York, NY).
Williamson, Oliver (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (Free Press, New
York, NY).
8
Zhao, Minyuan (2003), “Doing R&D in Countries with Weak IPR Protection: Can
Corporate Management Substitute for Legal Institutions?” mimeo, Stern School of
Business, New York University.
Zucker, Lynne G., Darby, Michael R., and Armstrong, Jeff S. (2001), “Commercializing
Knowledge: University Science, Knowledge Capture, and Firm Performance in
Biotechnology,” NBER Working Paper No. 8499.
9