University of California, Los Angeles
School of Law
Research Paper Series
UCLA
School of Law
Research Paper No. 03-7
This paper may be downloaded without charge at:
The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=389403
UCLA School of Law Los Angeles CA 90095-1476
STEPHEN M. BAINBRIDGE
The Creeping Federalization of Corporate Law
Regulation, Spring 2003
26 REGULATION SPRING 2003
For over 200 years, corporate governance has been a mat-
ter for state law. Even the vast expansion of the federal role
begun by the New Deal securities regulation laws left the inter-
nal affairs and governance of corporations to the states. To be
sure, over the years, there have been countless proposals to fed-
eralize corporate law. To date, however, none have succeeded.
The collapse of Enron and WorldCom, along with the varying
degrees of fraud uncovered at too many other companies, rein-
vigorated the debate over state regulation of corporate gover-
nance. Many politicians and pundits called for federal regulation
not just of securities but also of internal corporate governance,
claiming it would restore investor confidence in the securities
markets. As Congress and market regulators began implement-
ing some of those ideas, there has been a creeping — but steady
— federalization of corporate governance law. The nyse’s new
listing standards regulating director independence are one exam-
ple of that phenomenon. Other examples appeared to little pub-
lic debate in the sweeping Sarbanes-Oxley legislation. Taken indi-
vidually, each of Sarbanes-Oxley’s provisions constitutes a
significant preemption of state corporate law. Taken together, they
constitute the most dramatic expansion of federal regulatory
power over corporate governance since the New Deal.
WHO REGULATES CORPORATIONS?
No one seriously doubts that Congress has the power under the
Commerce Clause, especially as it is interpreted these days, to
create a federal law of corporations if it chooses. The question
of who gets to regulate public corporations thus is not one of
constitutional law but rather of prudence and federalism.
Until the New Deal, corporate law was exclusively a matter
SECURITIES & EXCHANGE
he new millennium has not been
kind to Wall Street. In 2000-’01, the stock
market recorded back-to-back years of loss-
es for the first time since 1973-’74. With a
further loss in 2002, the market fell for three
consecutive years for the first time since the
Great Depression.
On top of the continuing retrenchment of the economy fol-
lowing the late ’90s bubble, concerns over terrorism and the Mid-
dle East, and uncertainty over oil, investor confidence remains
shaky in the wake of last year’s corporate governance revelations.
We all know the litany: repeated accounting scandals, of which
Enron and WorldCom are merely the most notorious; a high pro-
file investigation by New York’s attorney general calling into ques-
tion the integrity of stock market analysts; and so on.
In such an environment, it was inevitable that Congress and
the Securities and Exchange Commission would step in to ease
investors’ fears. But how quickly we forget Ronald Reagan’s
adage: “The nine most terrifying words in the English language
are: ‘I’m from the government and I’m here to help.’”
In responding to the Enron and WorldCom scandals, Con-
gress and the regulators have implemented a set of reforms that
are deeply flawed. They have adopted policies that have no
empirical support or economic justification. Worse yet, in
doing so, they have eviscerated basic federalism rules that have
long served us well.
T
Stephen M. Bainbridge is a professor at the UCLA School of Law where he specializes in
business and corporate law. A prolific writer, Bainbridge recently released Corporation
Law and Economics (Foundation Press, 2002). He can be contacted by e-mail at
bainbridge@law.ucla.edu.
The Sarbanes-Oxley Act extends Washington’s oversight of corporate
governance practices but offers questionable benefits to investors.
The Creeping
Federalization of
Corporate Law
BY STEPHEN M. BAINBRIDGE
UCLA School of Law
Bainbridge.Final 3/13/03 2:34 PM Page 26
REGULATION SPRING 2003 27
for the states. Around the beginning of the last century, howev-
er, economic progressives began arguing for federal preemption
— frequently in response to various corporate scandals of the
day. After the Great Crash of 1929, serious consideration was
given to creating a federal law of corporations.
The New Dealers’ initial response to the Crash, of course,
consisted of the now familiar federal securities laws. The key
statute here is the Securities Exchange Act of 1934, which crit-
ics claimed was a federal attempt to usurp corporate gover-
nance powers. On its face, however, the Exchange Act says
nothing about regulation of corporate governance. Instead, the
Act’s basic focus is trading of securities and securities pricing.
Virtually all of its provisions are addressed to such matters as
the production and distribution of information about issuers
and their securities, the flow of funds in the market, and the
basic structure of the market.
While the federal securities laws thus left the internal affairs
and governance of corporations to the states, many New Deal-
ers refused to surrender
their hopes for a more
expansive federal role.
Throughout the 1930s,
there were repeated
proposals to federalize
corporate law. All failed.
Preserving federalism
Legislative inaction is
inherently ambiguous.
All that can be said with
certainty is that Con-
gress chose not to act.
Yet, the Supreme Court
nevertheless has rou-
tinely rejected regulato-
ry efforts to preempt
state law and create a de
facto federal law of cor-
porations. As the Court
noted in its 1987 deci-
sion in CTS Corp. v.
Dynamics Corp., “State
regulation of corporate
governance is regula-
tion of entities whose
very existence and
attributes are a product
of state law.” The Court
further noted that it “is
an accepted part of the
business landscape in
this country for states to
create corporations, to
prescribe their powers,
and to define the rights
that are acquired by
p urchasing their
shares.” Concluded the Court, “No principle of corporation law
and practice is more firmly established than a State’s authority
to regulate domestic corporations.”
It is state law, for example, that determines the rights of share-
holders. State law thus determines such questions as which mat-
ters the board of directors, acting alone, may authorize and
which must be authorized by the shareholders. State law typi-
cally requires, for example, that certain control transactions
such as mergers or sales of substantially all corporate assets be
approved in advance by the shareholders, and establishes the
vote required (often a supermajority) for shareholder approval
of such matters. State law likewise regulates the conduct of
shareholder meetings, specifies who may call such meetings,
and prescribes whether (and the procedures by which) actions
may be taken without a shareholder meeting.
The Supreme Court also has consistently recognized that
state law governs the rights and duties of corporate directors.
For instance, in its 1979 decision in Burks v. Lasker, the Court
MORGAN BALLARD
Bainbridge.Final 3/13/03 2:34 PM Page 27
28 REGULATION SPRING 2003
noted, “As we have said in the past, the first place one must look
to determine the powers of corporate directors is in the relevant
state’s corporation law. ‘Corporations are creatures of state law’
and it is state law which is the font of corporate directors’ pow-
ers.” State law defines the directors’ powers over the corpora-
tion, for example. State law establishes the vote required to elect
directors. State law determines whether shareholders have the
right to cumulative voting in the election of directors, whether
the corporation’s directors may have staggered terms of office,
and whether shareholders have the right to remove directors
prior to the expiration of their term of office.
Or, at least, it did so until recently.
The anti-federalists strike back For proponents of a bigger fed-
eral government, corporate scandals are always a bullish sig-
nal. There is nothing a politician wants more than to persuade
upset investors that he or she is “doing something” and being
“aggressive” in rooting out corporate fraud. Hence, it was
entirely predictable that the shenanigans at Enron, WorldCom,
et al., coming after a period of steady decline in the stock mar-
ket, would lead to regulation.
President Bush praised the Public Company Accounting
Reform and Investor Protection Act of 2002 — popularly
known as the Sarbanes-Oxley Act — for making “the most far-
reaching reforms of American business practices since the time
of Franklin Delano Roosevelt.” Odd praise, indeed, coming
from a conservative president. Such praise was especially odd
coming from a former state governor with a track record of
stated respect for basic federalism principles.
SARBANES-OXLEY AND CORPORATIONS
Because auditing failures by accounting firms, especially Arthur
Andersen, received a substantial share of the blame for the Enron
and WorldCom debacles, much of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act focus-
es on auditors and their relationship to public corporations. In
regulating that relationship, however, Congress for the first time
regulated such matters as the composition, role, and function of
the board of directors of public corporations. For example, Sar-
banes-Oxley requires national securities exchanges (such as the
New York Stock Exchange and nasdaq) to adopt listing stan-
dards mandating that listed companies have an audit commit-
tee and that that committee be comprised solely of independent
directors. At least one member of the committee must qualify
as a “financial expert” as defined by the statute. Given the nyse
and nasdaq’s recent expansion of their director independence
standards, it is not clear that those provisions will result in any
substantial new regulation. At the very least, however, they con-
firm and endorse the troubling expansion of stock exchange list-
ing standards that displace state corporate law.
The audit committee must establish a system for employ-
ees to blow the whistle anonymously on questionable account-
ing or auditing matters. Also, the audit committee is charged
with being “directly responsible for the appointment, com-
pensation, and oversight” of the corporation’s independent
auditor. If that provision is interpreted to preclude not only cor-
porate officers but also the board of directors as a whole from
being involved in the hiring and firing of independent auditors,
the provision will mark a substantial restriction on the power
of the board. Finally, the audit committee is granted federal
authority to retain independent legal and financial advisers
whose fees are paid by the board. Each of those provisions pre-
empts state law governing the board of directors.
Directors and officers The Act also partially preempts state
law governing the appointment, removal, and compensation
of directors and officers. As to the former, the sec is now
empowered to remove officers and directors from their posi-
tions, as well as bar them from serving at other public corpo-
rations, on mere grounds of “unfitness.”
As to the latter, executive compensation long has been a
controversial issue. Many critics of state corporate law com-
plain that it does not do enough to limit allegedly excessive
compensation. While Sarbanes-Oxley does not directly regu-
late executive compensation, it does contain a number of pro-
visions that do so indirectly. First, in the event a corporation is
obliged to restate its financial statements because of miscon-
duct, the chief executive officer and chief financial officer must
return to the corporation any bonus, incentive, or equity-based
compensation they received during the 12 months following
the original issuance of the restated financials, along with any
profits they realized from the sale of corporate stock during
that period.
There are many objections to that provision:
■ It preempts the board’s power over executive com-
pensation.
■ It fails to define the kinds of misconduct that trigger
the reimbursement obligation.
■ It requires reimbursement even if others committed
the misconduct, and extends to the officers no good-
faith defense.
All of those problems will tend to encourage ceos and cfos
to resist restating flawed financial statements and/or to game
the timing of their compensation and stock transactions rela-
tive to any such restatements.
Second, the Act prohibits a corporation from directly or indi-
rectly making or even arranging for loans to its directors and
executive officers, subject to some minor exceptions. That pro-
vision directly preempts the interested-party transaction provi-
sions of state corporate law, which currently permit the making
of loans to directors and officers provided they are authorized
by a majority of the disinterested directors or the shareholders.
Worse yet, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act fails to define many key
terms. Under state corporate law indemnification statutes, for
example, corporations frequently do (and in some cases must)
advance legal expenses to covered officers and directors. Given
the sweeping language of the Act’s prohibition on insider loans,
some observers believe it preempts state law in that respect and
therefore prohibits any such advancement of funds.
Finally, the Act prohibits executives from trading during so-
called blackout periods in which employees participating in
401(k) and other stock-based pension plans are forbidden from
SECURITIES & EXCHANGE
Bainbridge.Final 3/13/03 2:34 PM Page 28
REGULATION SPRING 2003 29
trading. If the executive does so, the corporation may sue to
receive any profits. If the corporation fails to do so, a share-
holder may bring a derivative action à la the short-swing prof-
it provision under §16(b).
Even when we turn from the provisions of the Act that direct-
ly mandate substantive corporate behavior to those that purport
merely to regulate disclosure, we find that many provisions
effectively displace applicable state corporate law. The relevant
concept here is so-called “therapeutic disclosure.” In other
words, the Act uses disclosure requirements to effect changes
in substantive behavior. For example, the corporation must dis-
close whether it has adopted a code of ethics for its financial offi-
cers. The Act identifies a host of issues the code must address,
such as the handling of conflicts of interest and the like. If a
company has not adopted such a code, it must disclose its rea-
sons for not doing so. In addition, the corporation’s manage-
ment must annually issue an “internal control report” in which
management acknowledges its responsibility for establishing
and maintaining adequate internal financial reporting controls
and assesses the effectiveness of those controls.
Even the widely touted requirement that the ceo and cfo cer-
tify the corporation’s financial statements effects stealth pre-
emptions of state law. Under that provision, the ceo and cfo are
made responsible for the establishment, design, and maintenance
of the corporation’s internal financial controls. Hence, corporate
boards have lost their freedom under state law to assign those
duties to other corporate officers (let alone to omit such controls).
State law governing the board’s oversight responsibilities is fur-
ther preempted by provisions requiring that the ceo and cfo
report directly to the audit committee on an array of issues deal-
ing with internal controls and financial reporting.
OTHER OVERSEERS
Congress is not the only regulator getting into the act. Under
the nyse aegis, a blue ribbon panel of usual-suspect Brahmins
has “anointed boards of directors, especially ‘independent
directors’ as the capitalist cavalry.” Acting on the panel’s rec-
ommendations, the nyse adopted new stock exchange listing
standards requiring that independent directors comprise a
majority of any listed corporation’s board of directors. The new
standards also effect a number of changes to the nyse’s long-
standing audit committee standards, which anticipate (and
even exceed) those mandated by Sarbanes-Oxley.
Director independence The utility of director independence
is now so deeply established in the conventional wisdom that
it seems almost pointless to ask if corporations really need a
majority of independent directors. But when one answers that
question, it turns out to be pretty complicated.
The theoretical arguments are complex and highly con-
tested. But we can cut to the bottom line: If independent direc-
tors have utility, there should be an identifiable correlation
between the presence of outsiders on the board and firm per-
formance. Yet, the empirical data on the issue is decidedly
mixed. In fact, the bulk of the evidence suggests that board
composition has no effect on profitability.
Anecdotal evidence confirms the view that board inde-
pendence is hardly a panacea for all that ails corporate gover-
nance: The head of Enron’s audit committee, Robert Jaedicke,
was a professor of accounting at Stanford University and could
hardly have been more qualified for the job. And we all know
what happened at Enron.
Managerial accountability The new standards imposed by the
nyse and Sarbanes-Oxley are premised on the conventional wis-
dom that board independence is an unalloyed good. As we have
seen, the empirical evidence on the merits of board independ-
ence is mixed, at best. Indeed, the clearest take-home lesson to
be gleaned from that evidence is that one size does not fit all.
That result should not be surprising. On one side of the
equation, firms do not have uniform needs for managerial
accountability mechanisms. The need for accountability is
determined by the likelihood of shirking, which in turn is
determined by management’s tastes, which in turn is deter-
mined by each firm’s unique culture, traditions, and compet-
itive environment. We all know managers whose preferences
include a penchant for hard, faithful work. Firms where that
sort of manager dominates the corporate culture have less need
for outside accountability mechanisms.
On the other side of the equation, firms have a wide range
of accountability mechanisms from which to choose. Inde-
pendent directors are not the sole mechanism by which man-
agement’s performance is monitored. Rather, a variety of forces
work together to constrain management’s incentive to shirk: the
capital and product markets within which the firm functions,
the internal and external markets for managerial services, the
market for corporate control, incentive compensation systems,
auditing by outside accountants, and many others. The impor-
tance of the independent directors’ monitoring role in a given
firm depends in large measure on the extent to which those
other forces are allowed to function. For example, managers of
a firm with strong takeover defenses are less subject to the con-
straining influence of the market for corporate control than are
those of a firm with no takeover defenses. The former needs a
strong independent board more than the latter does.
The critical mass of independent directors needed to provide
optimal levels of accountability also will vary depending upon the
types of outsiders chosen. Strong, active, independent directors
with little tolerance for negligence or culpable conduct do exist.
A board having a few such directors is more likely to act as a faith-
ful monitor than is a board having many nominally independent
directors who shirk their monitoring obligations.
Federal preemption The nyse’s new standards strap all list-
ed companies into a single model of corporate governance. By
establishing a highly restrictive definition of director inde-
pendence and mandating that such directors dominate both
the board and its required committees, the nyse fails to take
into account the diversity and variance among firms. The nyse
and Congress therefore should have allowed each firm to devel-
op the particular mix of monitoring and management that best
suits its individual needs.
The nyse should be especially cautious about promulgat-
ing corporate governance listing standards because such stan-
Bainbridge.Final 3/13/03 2:34 PM Page 29
SECURITIES & EXCHANGE
dards effectively preempt state corporate law by creating a uni-
form quasi-federal law of public corporations. There is no rea-
son to believe that the exchanges will do a better job of creat-
ing corporate law than do the states; indeed, there is good
reason to believe that they will do a worse job. In addition, by
virtue of the sec’s considerable influence over the exchanges,
the expansion of exchange listing standards in the corporate
governance area permits a backdoor power grab by the sec
over matters that Congress and the courts have left to the states.
By virtue of the unique relationship between the sec and the
exchanges, the commission naturally exercises considerable
informal influence over exchange rulemaking. The late Don-
ald Schwartz aptly referred to that influence as the sec’s “raised
eyebrow” power. In light of the adoption of the nyse com-
mittee’s initiatives, the exchanges role in corporate governance
— and, hence, the sec’s ability to influence the rules by which
corporations are governed — will expand dramatically. Federal
preemption of state corporation law will have finally arrived,
at least de facto.
FEDERALISM AND INCORPORATION
Who has it right — Congress or the states? Does the Supreme
Court’s defense of what might be called “corporate federalism”
make policy sense?
The basic case for federalizing corporate law rests on the so-
called “race to the bottom” hypothesis. States compete in grant-
ing corporate charters. After all, the more charters the state
grants, the more franchise and other taxes it collects. Accord-
ing to the race to the bottom theory, because it is corporate man-
agers who decide on the state of incorporation, states compete
by adopting statutes allowing corporate managers to exploit
shareholders. As the clear winner in this state competition,
Delaware is usually the poster-child for bad corporate gover-
nance. Interestingly, the two main poster-children for reform,
Enron and WorldCom, were not Delaware corporations; they
were incorporated in Oregon and Georgia, respectively.
Basic economic common sense tells us that investors will not
purchase, or at least not pay as much for, securities of firms
incorporated in states that cater too excessively to management.
Lenders will not lend to such firms without compensation for
the risks posed by management’s lack of accountability. As a
result, those firms’ cost of capital will rise, while their earnings
will fall. Among other things, such firms become more vul-
nerable to a hostile takeover and subsequent management
purges. Corporate managers therefore have strong incentives to
incorporate the business in a state offering rules preferred by
investors. Competition for corporate charters thus should deter
states from adopting excessively pro-management statutes.
Academic research The empirical research bears out that view
of state competition, suggesting that efficient solutions to cor-
porate law problems win out over time. Consider the following:
Roberta Romano’s event study of corporations changing
their domicile by reincorporating in Delaware, for example,
found that such firms experienced statistically significant pos-
itive cumulative abnormal returns. In other words, reincor-
porating in Delaware increased shareholder wealth. That find-
ing strongly supports the race to the top hypothesis. If share-
holders thought that Delaware was winning a race to the bot-
tom, shareholders should dump the stock of firms that rein-
corporate in Delaware, driving down the stock price of such
firms. As Romano found, and all of the other major event stud-
ies confirm, there is a positive stock price effect upon reincor-
poration in Delaware.
The event study findings are buttressed by Robert Daines’
study comparing the Tobin’s Q of Delaware and non-Delaware
corporations. (Tobin’s Q is the ratio of a firm’s market value to
its book value and is a widely accepted measure of firm value.)
Daines found that Delaware corporations in the period 1981-
1996 had a higher Tobin’s Q than those of non-Delaware cor-
porations, suggesting that Delaware law increases sharehold-
er wealth. Although subsequent research suggests that the
effect may not hold for all periods, Daines’ study remains an
important confirmation of the event study data.
Additional support for the event study findings is provided
by takeover regulation. Compared to most states, which have
adopted multiple anti-takeover statutes of ever-increasing
ferocity, Delaware’s single takeover statute is relatively friend-
ly to hostile bidders. An empirical study of state corporation
codes by John Coates confirms that the Delaware statute is the
least restrictive and imposes the least delay on a hostile bidder.
Given the clear evidence that hostile takeovers increase share-
holder wealth, Coates’ finding is especially striking. The sup-
posed poster child of bad corporate governance, Delaware,
turns out to be quite takeover-friendly and, by implication,
equally shareholder-friendly.
Federalism and liberty The takeover regulation evidence is
especially important because state anti-takeover laws are the
principal arrow in the quiver of modern race-to-the-bottom
theorists. In a series of articles, Lucian Bebchuk and his co-
authors point out that state takeover regulation demonstrably
reduces shareholder wealth but that most states have never-
theless adopted anti-takeover statutes. Even many advocates of
the race-to-the-top hypothesis concede that state regulation of
corporate takeovers appears to be an exception to the rule that
efficient solutions tend to win out. But so what? Nobody claims
that state competition is perfect. The question is only whether
some competition is better than none. Delaware’s relatively
hospitable environment for takeovers suggests an affirmative
answer to that question.
Bebchuk et al.’s arguments in favor of federal preemption,
moreover, betray a complete lack of sympathy for the vital rela-
tionship between federalism and liberty. In other words, even
if Bebchuk could prove that state competition is a race to the
bottom, basic federalism principles would still counsel against
federal preemption of corporate law. The corporation is a crea-
ture of the state “whose very existence and attributes are a prod-
uct of state law.” States have an interest in overseeing the firms
they create. States also have an interest in protecting the share-
holders of their corporations. Finally, as the Court noted in CTS
v. Dynamics, a state has a legitimate “interest in promoting sta-
ble relationships among parties involved in the corporations
it charters, as well as in ensuring that investors in such corpo-
30 REGULATION SPRING 2003
Bainbridge.Final 3/13/03 2:34 PM Page 30
rations have an effective voice in corporate affairs.” In other
words, state regulation not only protects shareholders, but also
protects investor and entrepreneurial confidence in the fairness
and effectiveness of the state corporation law.
According to the Supreme Court’s CTSdecision, the country
as a whole benefits from state regulation in this area. As Justice
Powell explained, the markets that facilitate national and inter-
national participation in ownership of corporations are essen-
tial for providing capital not only for new enterprises but also for
established companies that need to expand their businesses. This
beneficial free market system depends at its core upon the fact
that corporations generally are organized under, and governed
by, the law of the state of their incorporation. That is so in large
part because ousting the states from their traditional role as the
primary regulators of corporate governance would eliminate a
valuable opportunity for experimentation with alternative solu-
tions to the many difficult regulatory problems that arise in cor-
porate law. As Justice Brandeis famously pointed out in his dis-
senting opinion to New York Ice Co. v. Liebman, “It is one of the
happy incidents of the federal system that a single courageous
state may, if its citizens choose, serve as a laboratory and try novel
social and economic experiments without risk to the rest of the
country.” So long as state legislation is limited to regulation of
firms incorporated within the state, as it generally is, there is no
risk of conflicting rules applying to the same corporation. Exper-
imentation thus does not result in confusion, but instead may
lead to more efficient corporate law rules.
In contrast, the uniformity imposed by Sarbanes-Oxley will
preclude experimentation with differing modes of regulation.
As such, there will be no opportunity for new and better reg-
ulatory ideas to be developed — no “laboratory” of federalism.
Instead, we will be stuck with rules that may well be wrong
from the outset and, in any case, may quickly become obsolete.
The point is not merely to restate the race to the top argu-
ment. Competitive federalism promotes liberty as well as share-
holder wealth. When firms may freely select among multiple
competing regulators, oppressive regulation becomes imprac-
tical. If one regulator overreaches, firms will exit its jurisdiction
and move to one that is more laissez-faire. In contrast, when
there is but a single regulator, exit is no longer an option and
an essential check on excessive regulation is lost.
In other words, by promoting the economic freedom to pur-
sue wealth, competitive federalism does more than just expand
the economic pie. A legal system that pursues wealth maxi-
mization necessarily must allow individuals freedom to pursue
the accumulation of wealth. Economic liberty, in turn, is a nec-
essary concomitant of personal liberty — the two have almost
always marched hand in hand. The pursuit of wealth has been
a major factor in destroying arbitrary class distinctions, more-
over, by enhancing personal and social mobility. At the same
time, the manifest failure of socialist systems to deliver reason-
able standards of living has undermined their viability as an alter-
native to democratic capitalist societies in which wealth maxi-
mization is a paramount societal goal. Accordingly, it seems fair
to argue that the economic liberty to pursue wealth is an effec-
tive means for achieving a variety of moral ends.
In turn, the modern public corporation has turned out to
be a powerful engine for focusing the efforts of individuals to
maintain the requisite sphere of economic liberty. Those
whose livelihoods depend on corporate enterprise cannot be
neutral about political systems. Only democratic capitalist
societies permit voluntary formation of private corporations
and allot them a sphere of economic liberty within which to
function, which gives those who value such enterprises a pow-
erful incentive to resist both statism and socialism. As Michael
Novak observed in Toward a Theology of the Corporation, private
property and freedom of contract were “indispensable if pri-
vate business corporations were to come into existence.” In
turn, the corporation gives “liberty economic substance over
and against the state.”
CONCLUSION
What then is to be done? In the first place, Congress should
back off. Edmund Burke famously echoed Plato in his assertion
that prudence was the chief virtue of true statesmen. Prudence
demands that the law of unintended consequences be given its
due. The prudent legislator is hesitant to promulgate purported
reforms that may give rise to new and unforeseen abuses worse
than the evil to be cured. Sarbanes-Oxley’s many so-called
reforms likely to do just that. At the very least, prudence
demands that Congress allow Sarbanes-Oxley to shake out and
reveal its flaws before attempting further tinkering.
Second, in implementing Sarbanes-Oxley, the sec and other
regulators must pay due respect to the principles of federalism
that have governed corporation law since the New Deal. As a
general rule of thumb, federal law appropriately is concerned
mainly with disclosure obligations, as well as procedural and
antifraud rules designed to make disclosure more effective. In
contrast, regulating the substance of corporate governance stan-
dards is appropriately left to the states. Sarbanes-Oxley disrupted
that balance. The sec now should set about restoring it.
REGULATION SPRING 2003 31
READINGS
?
“A Critique of the nyse’s Director Independence Listing
Standards,” by Stephen M. Bainbridge. Securities Regulation Law
Journal, Vol. 30 (2002).
?
“Does Delaware Law Improve Firm Values?” by Robert
Daines. Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 62 (2001).
?
“Federalism and Corporate Law: The Race to Protect
Managers from Takeovers,” by Lucian Ayre Bebchuk and Allen
Ferrell. Columbia Law Review, Vol. 99 (1999).
?
“Law as a Product: Some Pieces of the Incorporation Puzzle,”
by Roberta Romano. Journal of Legal Economics and Organization,
Vol. 1 (1985).
R
Bainbridge.Final 3/13/03 2:34 PM Page 31