347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 101 The Surprising Virtues of the New Financial Privacy Law Peter P. Swire? The financial privacy law passed by Congress in 1999 has been the target of scathing criticism. On one side, banks and other financial institutions have complained about the high costs of the billions of notices sent to consumers, apparently to widespread consumer indifference. 1 On the other side, privacy advocates have condemned the law as woefully weak, and some have argued that its so-called privacy provisions actually re- sulted in weakening privacy protection. 2 This paper disagrees with the criticisms. The new finan- cial privacy law, known more formally as Title V of the Gramm- Leach-Bliley Act of 1999, works surprisingly well as privacy legislation. It does so in ways that address legitimate industry concerns about excessive cost and barriers to needed informa- tion. In addition, the ability of states to draft additional legis- lation in the area means that an effective mechanism exists to correct the key weaknesses of the law over time. ? Professor of Law, the Moritz College of Law of the Ohio State Univer- sity. From March, 1999 to January, 2001 I served as Chief Counselor for Pri- vacy in the U.S. Office of Management and Budget. My thanks to helpful comments from participants in the Minnesota Law Review Symposium on Pri- vacy. My thanks also for comments by Rick Fischer, Lauren Steinfeld, and Art Wilmarth, and to Larry Glasser for research assistance. 1. For instance, one estimate was that the financial privacy rules would require 2.5 billion consumer disclosure statements annually, with a compli- ance cost of compliance (which I believe is high) of $1.25 billion. Michele Heller, Banks Want More Time on Reform’s Privacy Rules, AM. BANKER, Apr. 12, 2000, at 3. 2. Frank Torres, legislative counsel for Consumers Union and an active participant in the legislative debates, bluntly described the new privacy law: “The much ballyhooed privacy provision of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act does not protect consumers’ privacy.” Don Oldenberg, To-Do Over Privacy Legisla- tion, WASH. POST, April 5, 2000, at C4. Torres also lamented: “[GLB] has a few meager privacy provisions, but it contains so many exceptions that it gives consumers no real privacy protection at all.” Steven Brostoff, Privacy Legisla- tion Draws Industry Fire, NAT’L UNDERWRITER LIFE & HEALTH-FIN. SERVICES EDITION, May 8, 2000, at 46. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 102 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp The financial privacy provisions were enacted in 1999 as part of sweeping legislation to update the structure of the banking, insurance, securities, and other financial services in- dustries. Since the 1930’s, the Glass-Steagall Act had largely separated these industries. Gramm-Leach-Bliley, as signed by President Clinton in November, 1999, culminated many years of regulatory and legislative debate about how to modernize the financial services sector. From now on, a single financial hold- ing company can own banks, investment banks, insurance companies, and a wide array of other institutions. Part I of this article introduces the main provisions of Title V, showing the better match with basic privacy principles than many have realized. Part II explores the history of how the fi- nancial privacy provisions became law, placing the enactment into the context of a historical peak of privacy policy activity in the late 1990’s. Perhaps this history will be of particular inter- est because of my unusual dual perspective, both as an aca- demic who has written extensively about financial privacy, 3 and also as the Clinton Administration’s Chief Counselor for Privacy during the period. Part III looks at the most hotly-contested issue in the pri- vacy debate, the rules for sharing personal information with af- filiated entities and third parties. GLB establishes a basic rule that information can flow freely within a financial institution and to its affiliates. Customer choice—an opt-out ability to prevent sharing—applies for transfers to non-affiliated compa- nies. This article argues that an exception to that principle of customer choice, the so-called “joint marketing exception,” should be repealed. It then explores the knotty issue of how to handle data sharing in today’s vast financial conglomerates, suggesting a number of possible modifications to GLB’s Title V. Part IV of the article looks at the much-maligned notices that financial institutions have sent out in compliance with GLB. The critics have accurately complained about the legalis- tic and detailed language in the current notices. The critics have largely overlooked, however, important benefits from these notices. Perhaps most significantly, publication of the 3. PETER P. SWIRE & ROBERT E. LITAN, NONE OF YOUR BUSINESS: WORLD DATA FLOWS, ELECTRONIC COMMERCE, AND THE EUROPEAN PRIVACY DIRECTIVE 102-21 (1998); Peter Swire, Financial Privacy and the Theory of High-Tech Government Surveillance, 77 WASH. U. L.Q. 461 (1999); Peter P. Swire, The Uses and Limits of Financial Cryptography: A Law Professor’s Per- spective (1997), available at www.osu.edu/units/law/swire.htm. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 103 notices and the new legal obligation to comply with them has forced financial institutions to engage in considerable self- scrutiny as to their data handling practices. The current no- tices, even in their imperfect form, have reduced the risk of egregious privacy practices. Improved notices, as described in this article, would enhance accountability while also communi- cating far more clearly with ordinary customers. In short, this article shows the surprising merits of the GLB privacy provisions. Considerably more was accomplished in the Act than observers would have predicted in the spring of 1999 or than critics have recognized to date. Important flaws do exist, but specific and achievable changes in the statute and implementing regulations can go far toward reducing the mag- nitude of those flaws. I. THE PRIVACY PROVISIONS IN GRAMM-LEACH-BLILEY Perhaps the clearest way to understand what was and was not enacted in the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (GLB) on privacy is to compare the law as enacted with standard definitions of fair information practices. Codes of fair information practices are an organizing theme of privacy protection. They were first set forth in comprehensive form in a United States Department of Health, Education, and Welfare study in 1973. 4 The precise list of fair information practices has varied somewhat over time, but the use of such a list has been a standard feature of privacy regimes. For instance, they are incorporated into United States law in the Privacy Act of 1974, which applies to United States federal agencies. 5 They are listed as the “core princi- ples” of the most important consensus document internation- ally, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Develop- ment Guidelines on the Protection of Privacy and Transborder Flows of Personal Data, issued in 1980. They are central to the European Union Directive on Data Protection, issued in final form in 1995 and binding on the fifteen member states of the European Union. 6 In the 1990s, as the rise of the Internet 4. U.S. DEPT. HEALTH, EDUC. & WELFARE, Records, Computers and the Rights of Citizens (1973). 5. Privacy Act of 1974, 5 U.S.C. § 552a (2000). 6. Council Directive 95/46/EC on the Protection of Individuals with Re- gard to the Processing of Personal Data and the Free Movement of Such Data, 1995 O.J. (L 281) 31 (Oct. 24, 1995), available at http://europea.eu.int/eur- lex/en/lif/dat/1995/en_395L0046.html [hereinafter European Union Data Pro- tection Directive]. See generally PETER P. SWIRE & ROBERT E. LITAN, NONE OF 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 104 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp helped make privacy a more prominent public policy issue in the United States, the fair information practices were used as organizing principles for the debate. Likely the best known version was that of the Federal Trade Commission, which con- tained five principles: notice/awareness; choice/consent; ac- cess/participation; integrity/security; and enforcement/redress. 7 A. NOTICE The FTC calls notice “[t]he most fundamental princi- ple . . . .” 8 Without notice, the consumer “cannot make an in- formed decision as to whether and to what extent to disclose personal information.” 9 The notice principle is addressed in de- tail in GLB, although debates continue about how best to pro- vide notice. The GLB notice requirements apply to “nonpublic personal information” (often described in this article as “personal infor- mation” or “personal data”). 10 This personal information may YOUR BUSINESS: WORLD DATA FLOWS, ELECTRONIC COMMERCE, AND THE EUROPEAN PRIVACY DIRECTIVE (1998). 7. Federal Trade Commission, Privacy Online: A Report to Congress (June 1998), available at http://www.ftc.gov/reports/privacy3/priv-23a.pdf [hereinafter 1998 FTC Report]. The list of the FTC, which is an independent agency, was generally consistent with formulations by the Clinton Admini- stration. See Information Infrastructure Task Force, Information Policy Com- mittee, Privacy Working Group, Privacy and the National Information Infra- structure: Principles for Providing and Using Personal Information (June 6, 1995), available at http://iitf.doc.gov/ipc/ipc/ipc-pubx/niiprivprin_final.html; U.S. Department of Commerce, Privacy and the NII: Safeguarding Telecom- munications-Related Personal Information (Oct.1995), available at http://www.ntia.doc.gov/ntiahome/privwhitepaper .html. 8. 1998 FTC Report, supra note 7, at 7. 9. Id. The 1980 OECD Guidelines state, in the Collection Limitation Principle: “There should be limits to the collection of personal data and any such data should be obtained by lawful and fair means and, where appropri- ate, with the knowledge or consent of the data subject.” Organization for Eco- nomic Cooperation and Development Guidelines on the Protection of Privacy and Transborder Flows of Personal Data, Sept. 23, 1980, OECD Dic, C(80) 58, reprinted in 20 I.L.M. 422, available at http://www1.oecd.org/dsti/sti/ it.secur/prod/PRIV-EN.HTM (latest update Jan. 5 1999) [hereinafter OECD Guidelines]. 10. The term “nonpublic personal information” is defined in GLB Section 6809(4) to mean “personally identifiable financial information (i) provided by a consumer to a financial institution; (ii) resulting from any transaction with the consumer or any service performed for the consumer; (iii) or otherwise ob- tained by the financial institution.” Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999, 15 U.S.C. § 6809(4)(A) (2000) [hereinafter GLB]. The term “does not include pub- licly available information.” Id. § 6809(4)(B). It does include “any list, de- scription, or other grouping of consumers . . . that is derived using any non- 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 105 not be disclosed to another corporation unless the consumer is provided a notice. 11 At the time of establishing a customer re- lationship, and at least annually after that, a financial institu- tion “shall provide a clear and conspicuous disclosure of the in- stitution’s privacy policies [to the consumer].” 12 The privacy policy must give the policies for sharing data with both affili- ates and nonaffiliated third parties, including the categories of information that may be disclosed. 13 The notice requirement of GLB is what led to the large number of individual privacy poli- cies that customers of financial institutions now receive on an annual basis. B. CHOICE/CONSENT. The choice/consent principle has been a major source of contention, both during passage of GLB and since. In the words of the FTC, “choice relates to secondary uses of informa- tion—i.e., uses beyond those necessary to complete the contem- plated transaction.” 14 Privacy regimes generally limit data uses to those that fulfill the original purposes of the data collec- tion, as well as others that are compatible with those pur- poses. 15 In interpreting the choice/consent principle, there have been heated debates about what the default rule should be. In- dustry has generally favored a default rule of allowing sharing, with customers able to opt out if they choose to limit the data flow. Privacy advocates have generally favored a default rule prohibiting sharing, with data going for secondary uses only with an affirmative opt in by the individual. The default rule seems to matter a great deal in the privacy context, because experience seems to show that the bulk of customers generally public personal information other than publicly available information . . . .” Id. §6809(4)(C). 11. Id. § 6802(a). 12. Id. 6803(a). 13. Id. § 6803(a)(1). 14. 1998 FTC Report, supra note 7, at 8. Similarly, under the 1980 OECD Guidelines, [t]he purposes for which personal data are collected should be speci- fied not later than at the time of data collection and subsequent use limited to the fulfillment of those purposes or such others as are not incompatible with those purposes. . . . Disclosure or use of data should then not be done except a) with the consent of the data subject; or b) by the authority of law.” OECD Guidelines, supra note 9. 15. See supra note 14. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 106 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp stick with whichever default rule applies in a given context. 16 The other heated debate has been about what sorts of shar- ing constitute secondary use. In the financial services area, in- dustry has pushed especially hard for the ability to share data with affiliates, that is, with companies controlled by the same financial holding company. 17 Industry has also supported the ability to share data with nonaffiliated third parties. 18 Privacy proponents have maintained that sharing with either affiliates or nonaffiliated third parties constitutes secondary use, and should trigger a choice or consent requirement. As enacted, GLB adopted the basic rule of requiring an opt- out choice before personal data could be shared with nonaffili- ated third parties. 19 Financial institutions must give notice be- fore they share data with affiliates, but customers are not enti- tled to an opt-out choice for affiliate sharing. 20 This basic rule is loosened in two ways. First, the “joint marketing exception” allows a financial institution to share information with nonaf- filiated financial institutions in order to pursue joint market- ing. 21 As discussed below, this exception has been controver- sial, and I believe it should be repealed. Second, the law sets forth a number of statutory exceptions where neither notice nor choice are required. These exceptions have been reasonably well accepted by many of the stakeholders in the privacy de- 16. This is my own view after experience with a wide range of privacy re- gimes. One example of the difference comes from the Drivers Privacy Protec- tion Act of 1999. 18 U.S.C. § 2721 (2000). The Act restricts a state motor ve- hicles bureau from sharing individual drivers license information for marketing purposes except with choice or consent. It was enacted as an opt- out regime in 1994. Id. As such, opt out rates varied, based on my discussions with officials, from the low single digits to a high in some states of about 20 percent. In 1999, an appropriation rider switched the regime to opt in. Transportation Appropriations Act., Pub. L. 106-346, § 309 __ Stat. ___, ___ (2000) (amending 18 U.S.C. § 2721). Since that time, no state has even asked whether individuals wished to consent to sharing their drivers license infor- mation for marketing purposes. 17. “The term ‘affiliate’ means any company that controls, is controlled by, or is under common control with another company.” GLB, supra note 10, § 6809(6). 18. “The term ‘nonaffiliated third party’ means any entity that is not an affiliate of, or related by common ownership or affiliated by corporate control with, the financial institution, but does not include a joint employee of such institution.” GLB, supra note 10, § 6809(5). 19. Id. § 6802(b)(1). 20. Id. § 6802(a). 21. Id. § 6802(b)(2). The joint marketing exception is discussed in detail text accompanying notes ___ infra. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 107 bates, and apply, for instance, to an institution’s attorneys, ac- countants, and auditors, to consumer reporting agencies under the Fair Credit Reporting Act, to protect against or prevent fraud, and to comply with authorized law enforcement investigations. 22 GLB is stricter than the basic rule in one respect. A finan- cial institution cannot disclose, other than to a consumer re- porting agency, a credit card or similar account number to any nonaffiliated third party for use in telemarketing, direct mail marketing, or e-mail marketing to a consumer. 23 The opt-out and account number restrictions are backed up by a limit on how third parties can redisclose the information. 24 C. ACCESS. The third core principle is access. Access refers “to an in- dividual’s ability both to access data about him or herself—i.e., to view the data in an entity’s files—and to contest that data’s accuracy and completeness.” 25 Individuals in the United States have had a right to access their credit history—an accumula- tion of sensitive personal financial information—since passage of the Fair Credit Reporting Act in 1970. 26 GLB itself does not implement any consumer access right. Proposed legislation, including that supported by President 22. Id. § 6802(e). Other exceptions, described in more detail in the stat- ute, include: an exception necessary to carry out a transaction; with the con- sent of the consumer; to protect the confidentiality or security of the institu- tion’s records; to provide information to persons assisting in compliance with industry standards; and in connection with a sale or merger of the business. Id. 23. Id. § 6802(d). 24. Essentially, a nonaffiliated third party that receives personal informa- tion shall not redisclose that information to any other person unless such dis- closure would be lawful if made directly to such other person by the original financial institution. Id. § 6892(c). 25. 1998 FTC Report, supra note 7, at 9. The OECD Individual Participa- tion Principle states: An individual should have the right: a) to obtain from a data control- ler, or otherwise, confirmation of whether or not the data controller has data relating to him; b) to have communicated to him, data relat- ing to him: within a reasonable time; at a charge, if any, that is not excessive; in a reasonable manner; and in a form that is readily intel- ligible to him; c) to be given reasons if a request made under subpara- graphs(a) and (b) is denied, and to be able to challenge such denial; and d) to challenge data relating to him and, if the challenge is suc- cessful to have the data erased, rectified, completed or amended. OECD Guidelines, supra note 9. 26. Fair Credit Reporting Act, 15 U.S.C. § 1681g (2000). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 108 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp Clinton in 2000, would have provided access rights to financial information as a matter of law. 27 In practice, however, con- sumers often have an ability to access their personal financial information. For important accounts such as checking ac- counts, credit card records, securities brokerage accounts, and the like, individuals generally receive detailed records as a matter of course, and they can contest the accuracy and com- pleteness of those records as problems arise. D. SECURITY As the FTC states: “Security involves both managerial and technical measures to protect against loss and the unauthor- ized access, destruction, use, or disclosure of the data.” 28 Pri- vacy policies offer little protection unless security is in place. Otherwise, the best-intended policies can be quickly under- mined by hackers or others who access and disclose the per- sonal information. GLB addresses security as part of the general obligation of financial institutions to protect privacy. The statute provides: “It is the policy of the Congress that each financial institution has an affirmative and continuing obligation to respect the pri- vacy of its customers and to protect the security and confidenti- 27. Consumer Financial Privacy Act, H.R. 4380, 106 th Cong. § 6 (2000) (amending GLB to add a new section that provides the right to access nonpub- lic personal financial information possessed by a financial institution); Finan- cial Information Privacy Protection Act of 2000, S. 2513, 106 th Cong. § 6 (2000) (same); Medical Financial Privacy Protection Act, H.R. 4585, 106 th Cong. § 2 (2000) (same for identifiable health information possessed by a financial insti- tution). 28. 1998 FTC Report, supra note 7, at 10. Similarly, the OECD Security Safeguards Principle states: “Personal data should be protected by reasonable security safeguards against such risks as loss or unauthorized access, destruc- tion, use, modification or disclosure of data.” OECD Guidelines, supra note 9. The FTC Report combines the security principle with the need to assure data integrity, where “collectors must take reasonable steps, such as using only reputable sources of data and cross-referencing data against multiple sources, providing consumer access to data, and destroying untimely data or converting it to anonymous form.” 1998 FTC Report, supra note 7, at 10. This definition of data integrity conforms to the principle, accepted in European countries, that “untimely data” should be destroyed or converted to anony- mous form. The Data Protection Directive, for instance, states that personal data must be “kept in a form which permits identification of data subjects for no longer than is necessary for the purposes for which the data were collected or for which they are further processed.” European Union Data Protection Di- rective, supra note 6, art. 6(e). Notwithstanding the FTC’s support for “de- stroying untimely data,” U.S. law has not usually included data destruction as a significant element of privacy principles. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 109 ality of those customers’ nonpublic personal information.” 29 In furtherance of that policy, regulators are required to issue standards relating to administrative, technical, and physical safeguards to protect the security and confidentiality of cus- tomer records and information. The standards must protect against “anticipated threats or hazards to the security or integ- rity of such records,” and protect as well against unauthorized access to records or information that “could result in substan- tial harm or inconvenience to any customer.” 30 E. ENFORCEMENT AND REMEDIES. The FTC says: “It is generally agreed that the core princi- ples of privacy protection can only be effective if there is a mechanism in place to enforce them.” 31 A phalanx of financial regulators have now issued regulations to implement the GLB privacy provisions for institutions in their jurisdiction. 32 In implementing these privacy regulations, the basic rule under GLB is that financial regulators can deploy the full powers that they use in other enforcement actions. 33 Bank regulators can use the strict enforcement powers that they gained after the savings and loan abuses of the late 1980s. 34 State insurance 29. GLB, supra note 10, § 6801(a). 30. Id. § 6801(b). 31. 1998 FTC Report, supra note 7, at 10. The OECD Accountability Principle states: “A data controller should be accountable for complying with measures which give effect to the principles stated above.” OECD Guidelines, supra note 9. 32. The statute required seven agencies, working together with the Treasury Department, to prepare regulations. GLB, supra note 10, § 6804(a)(1). First, a set of standards—”The Interagency Guidelines Establish- ing Standards for Safeguarding Customer Information”—were developed by the GLB agencies and uniformly promulgated. See, e.g., 12 C.F.R. § 30.2, app. B (Comptroller of the Currency); Id. § 208.3, app. D-2 (Federal Reserve); Id. § 364.101 app. B. (FDIC), Id. § 570.1, app. B (Office of Thrift Supervision), Id. § 748, app. A (NCUA). Second, the agencies each promulgated a rule that re- quired financial institutions within their jurisdiction to comply with the Guidelines. See, e.g., Id. § 208.3 (Federal Reserve); 16 C.F.R. § 313.1 (Federal Trade Commission); 12 C.F.R. § 364.101 (FDIC); Id. § 568.5 (Office of Thrift Supervision). GLB, supra note 10, § 509 (3)(B) specifically excluded the Commodity Futures Trading Commission from the Act, but that was reversed by The Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000. 7 U.S.C. § 1 278f (2000). The CFTC is- sued proposed rules for GLB compliance in early 2001. 66 Fed. Reg. 15,550 (March 19, 2001). 33. GLB, supra note 10, § 6805. 34. See 12 U.S.C. 1818 (2000). The bank regulators with these powers to enforce the privacy rules are the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 110 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp authorities enforce for violations by state-regulated insurance companies. 35 The Securities and Exchange Commission, Na- tional Credit Union Administration, and Commodities Future Trading Commission can enforce against entities in their juris- diction. The FTC can use its powers to enforce against unfair or deceptive trade practices against any other financial institu- tion that is not subject to one of the above agencies. F. SUMMARY ON GLB AND FAIR INFORMATION PRACTICES. When matched against the standard list of fair information practices, GLB provides a better set of privacy protections than many have realized. GLB creates significant legal protections for the notice, security, and enforcement principles. For access, ordinary industry practice likely meets many consumer needs. The largest debate concerns the choice/consent principle. Pri- vacy advocates are concerned that the opt-out choice is too weak and that too many data flows are permitted to affiliates and joint marketing partners without any choice at all. As dis- cussed below, the Clinton Administration proposed legislation in 2000 to address these problems, and I personally would favor additional legal protections in the choice/consent area. Other provisions in GLB show that it provides a better foundation for privacy protection than many have realized. First, the definition of “financial institutions,” which are cov- ered by the statute, is extremely broad. GLB allows a financial holding company to engage in any activity found by the Federal Reserve Board “to be financial in nature or incidental to such financial activity.” 36 Going beyond that broad definition, the Board can authorize an activity that is “complementary to a fi- nancial activity and does not pose a substantial risk” to safety and soundness. 37 This broad definition is an advantage for banks and other institutions that are clearly financial in na- ture, because they are clearly covered by the privacy rules and can now combine with a wider range of entities. The broad Federal Reserve Board, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, the Office of Thrift Supervision. 35. Because of federalism limits against “commandeering” the states in a federal statutory scheme, see New York v. United States, 505 U.S. 144 (1992), the statute does not order state insurance authorities to adopt regulations to carry out the privacy protections. Instead, states that decline to adopt regula- tions will lose the power to override certain federal banking regulations. GLB, supra note 10, § 6805(c). 36. 12 U.S.C. 1843(k)(1)(A) (2000). 37. 12 U.S.C. 1843(k)(1)(B ) (2000) (emphasis added). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 111 definition, however, also has the effect of bringing more entities within the scope of GLB privacy protections than would be ap- parent from the term “financial institutions.” Examples in- clude many travel agencies, law firms that provide tax and fi- nancial planning advice, and retail stores with installment credit operations. 38 The reach of the privacy protections is thus greater than many initially realized. State law may also operate in ways that make GLB more powerful for privacy than the statute would be standing alone. As enacted, GLB specifically provides that it acts as a floor, but states may provide stricter privacy protections if they so choose. 39 As discussed below, this possibility of additional state legislation serves as an important goad for financial institu- tions to reassure state legislators and the general public that they are treating sensitive data with the appropriate level of confidentiality. Stricter state law may turn out to be especially important in the enforcement area. GLB does not provide a private right of action. The statutory language on relation to state law, however, specifically permits an “order” or “interpre- tation” to be stricter at the state level. 40 This language may be important in the context of a state tort or contract claim that alleges that a financial institution failed to protect a customer’s privacy. Even if GLB itself does not create the private right of action, the statute appears to allow the state claim to proceed to an eventual “order” by a judge who may “interpret” federal and state law. In a tort case, for instance, a bank’s violation of the federal privacy regulation may assist a plaintiff in showing that the bank violated a standard of reasonable care. The level of privacy protection contemplated by GLB may turn out to highly relevant to what is held to be a breach of duty in state court. II. THE HISTORY AND RATIONALE OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LEGISLATION The financial privacy provisions of GLB Title V were not inevitable. Indeed, financial reform came very close to passage in 1998 without having any noticeable privacy provisions. 41 In 38. The definition of “financial institutions” clearly includes many travel agencies. 16 C.F.R. § 313.1 (2002). For an additional discussion of the breadth of the term “financial services,” see 65 Fed. Reg. 33,647 (May 24, 2000). 39. GLB, supra note 10, § 6807(b). 40. Id. 41. See Financial Services Competitiveness Act of 1997, H.R. 10, 105th 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 112 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp 1999, by contrast, privacy became a leading political issue in the legislative debates. President Clinton put forward privacy proposals in May. 42 The House of Representatives almost unanimously passed a privacy amendment in July, 43 most of whose provisions were signed into law in November. 44 Upon signing the bill, furthermore, President Clinton called for addi- tional privacy protections in future legislation, 45 and the Ad- ministration proposed such legislation in the spring of 2000. 46 These financial privacy developments, furthermore, hap- pened alongside heated debates on medical privacy, Internet privacy, and related topics. How can we capture the reasons why privacy and data protection issues climbed so swiftly up the policy agenda in the United States in the past few years? To answer this question requires us to recognize that we are currently in the second major wave of privacy law reform, and to understand what differs from the first major wave. A. THE FIRST WAVE OF PRIVACY LEGISLATION The first major wave of privacy activity took place in the early 1970’s, largely in response to the rise of the mainframe computer. The chief worry in that period was the spectre of the enormous, centralized database. The chief areas of concern, as evidenced by the passage of legislation, were credit reporting agencies and the federal government. For credit histories, the concern was that the fragmented Cong. (1998); see also Leslie Wayne, Senate Panel Delays Vote on Overhaul of Banking Laws, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 4, 1998, at C4 (bill delayed even though “[m]omentum had been building in Congress for the Senate to take up the measure before adjourning in October”). 42. Press Release, The White House, Press Background Briefing by Senior Administration Officials on Financial Privacy (Apr. 30, 2000), available at www.privacy2000.org/archives/POTUS_4-30- 00_press_background_briefing_on_financial_privacy_htm. 43. The Oxley Amendment to H.R. 19 was agreed to by a vote of 427 to 1 on July 1, 1999. See H. Res. 235, 106th CONG. REC. 5304-16 (1999). 44. GLB, supra note 10, §§ 6801-09. 45. President William Clinton, Remarks by the President at Financial Modernization Bill Signing (Nov. 12, 1999), available at www.privacy2000.org/archives/POTUS_11-12- 99_Remarks_by_president_at_financial_moderniztion_bill%20signing.htm. 46. Press Release, The White House, Office of the Press Secretary, Clin- ton-Gore Plan to Enhance Consumers’ Financial Privacy: Protecting Core Val- ues in the Information Age, (Apr. 30, 2000), available at www.privacy2000.org/archives. The Administration’s bill was introduced in the Congress as H.R. 4380 and S. 2513. See supra note 27. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 113 legacy of local credit agencies was turning into a few nation- spanning databases. The newly national databases, according to contemporary studies, contained a disturbingly large amount of unverified and often incorrect information. Individuals were apparently being turned down for mortgages or jobs based on inaccurate information, some of which was provided by careless or malicious persons. 47 In the face of these concerns about the centralized databases, Congress passed the Fair Credit Report- ing Act in 1970. 48 The Act establishes a number of fair infor- mation practices, including individuals’ right to access their own records and to seek to correct mistakes in those records. 49 A similar fear of centralized databases led to the Privacy Act of 1974, which governs the creation and use of federal gov- ernment systems of records. 50 The fear of Big Brother—a uni- fied and government-run database—was an important motiva- tion for the Privacy Act. A crucial feature of the Act generally prohibits transfers from one federal agency to another except with the individual’s consent. 51 Whatever the imperfections in the reach or application of the Privacy Act, 52 it has succeeded in preventing the creation of the omnivorous, unified federal da- tabase. Since 1974, a number of significant privacy laws have been adopted in the United States, covering such areas as govern- ment access to financial records, 53 searches of materials related to publication and broadcast, 54 cable television records, 55 elec- tronic wiretaps, 56 video records, 57 employee polygraph tests, 58 47. See generally ARTHUR R. MILLER, THE ASSAULT ON PRIVACY: COMPUTERS, DATA BANKS, AND DOSSIERS, (1971); L. RICHARD FISCHER, THE LAW OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY, ch. 1 (Warren, Gorham & Lamont Banking 1998). 48. 15 U.S.C. §§ 1681-1681U (2000). 49. Id. at § 1681g. 50. Privacy Act of 1974, 5 U.S.C. § 552a (2000). 51. Id. at § 552a(b). Transfers among agencies are also allowed in a num- ber of other statutory exceptions, including for “routine uses” that are pub- lished in the Federal Register. Id. 52. Robert Gellman, “How to Amend the Privacy Act,” Access Reports (1997). 53. Right to Financial Privacy Act of 1978, 12 U.S.C. §3402 (2000). 54. Privacy Protection Act of (1980), 42 U.S.C. § 2000aa (1994). 55. Cable Communications Policy Act of (1984), 47 U.S.C. § 551 (1996). 56. Electronic Communications Privacy Act of 1986, 18 U.S.C. § 2510- 2519 (2000). 57. Video Privacy Protection Act of 1998, 18 U.S.C. § 2710 (2000). 58. Employee Polygraph Protection Act of 1988, 29 U.S.C. § 2002 (1994). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 114 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp telemarketing calls, 59 motor vehicle records, 60 aspects of cus- tomer telephone records, 61 and children’s records for on-line ac- tivities. 62 Not until recently, however, has there seemed a real possibility of creating wide-ranging privacy rules that would reshape information practices in major economic sectors. Shifts in the underlying technology spurred the wave of privacy reform in the 1990s. 63 First, the fear in the 1970’s was prompted by the new mainframe technology. Today, everyone has a mainframe—a modern laptop or desktop computer out- performs the mainframes of the earlier era. The number of da- tabases has thus grown exponentially. Second, in the 1970’s, the Internet was only an experimental system available to some government agencies and scientific researchers. Today, transfers among computers are entirely different. For most practical purposes, transfers today are free, instantaneous, and global. The new databases and new transfers among databases led to a major spike in public concern about privacy issues. The public expressed concern that sensitive personal data was be- coming available in new ways to a new range of people. Per- haps the clearest message about the salience of privacy came from a Wall Street Journal poll in September, 1999, just as House and Senate negotiators were debating the privacy provi- sions in GLB. In the lead-up to the year 2000, the poll asked Americans what they feared most in the coming century. 64 Out of a dozen choices, including threats such as international ter- rorism, global warming, and nuclear holocaust, the leading an- swer was “erosion of personal privacy.” The poll reported that 29 percent of respondents put privacy either first or second out of the dozen choices. No other issue received more than 23 per- cent. 59. Telephone Consumer Protection Act of 1991, 47 U.S.C. § 227 (1994). 60. Driver’s Privacy Protection Act of 1994, 18 U.S.C. § 2721-2725 (1994). 61. Telecommunications Act of 1996, 47 U.S.C. § 222 (Supp. 111 1997). 62. Children’s On-Line Privacy Protection Act of 1998, 15 U.S.C. § 6501- 6505 (2000). The privacy statutes listed here, and other legal materials re- lated to privacy, are collected in Marc Rotenberg, THE PRIVACY LAW SOURCEBOOK 2000 (Electronic Privacy Information Center). (Have source, lo- cating) 63. The shift from mainframes to distributed processing is discussed in more detail in SWIRE & LITAN, supra note 6, at ch. 3. 64. Christy Harvey, American Opinion (A Special Report): Optimism Out- duels Pessimism, WALL ST. J., Sept. 16, 1999, at A10. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 115 B. THE SECOND WAVE: PRIVACY DEVELOPMENTS OUTSIDE OF FINANCIAL MODERNIZATION A comprehensive history of the privacy politics in the 1990s has yet to be written. For the present purpose, to under- stand the origins of Title V of GLB, we can identify some of the major aspects of the wave of policy activity in the late 1990s. Public attention focused most intensively on the growing issue of Internet privacy, especially information collected at web pages. The Clinton Administration early on gave some at- tention to the issue as part of the Information Superhighway project. The Federal Trade Commission became involved in Internet privacy by 1995. The FTC was increasingly viewed as the cop on the Internet beat due to its power to enforce against “unfair and deceptive” trade practices, such as violations of web privacy policies. Within the Administration, e-commerce leader Ira Magaziner announced the basic policy of encouraging in- dustry self-regulation in the summer of 1997. Secretary of Commerce William Daley personally became involved in en- couraging industry to improve privacy practices as part of the development of e-commerce. In May, 1998, Vice President Gore elevated the privacy is- sue to the White House level in a speech announcing an “Elec- tronic Bill of Rights.” 65 In this speech, and a follow-up event in July, 1998, the Vice President set forth a four-part policy struc- ture that the Administration essentially followed until the end of its second term. 66 First, the Vice President called for privacy legislation to protect especially sensitive information. This category of “sensitive” information initially included medical records, children’s activities on-line, and some financial re- cords. Second, the Administration supported self-regulation for privacy in other areas, while continually pushing industry to take effective steps to improve privacy protection. The implicit understanding was that the Administration might switch to supporting Internet privacy legislation if industry did not act effectively. Third, the Federal government should act as a model for good privacy practices. Fourth, the Office of Man- 65. Vice President Gore announced the electronic bill of rights at a New York University Commencement speech. White House, Vice President Gore Announces New Comprehensive Privacy Action Plan for the 21st Century, (May 14, 1998), available at www.privacy2000.org/archives. 66. Office of the Vice President, “Vice President Gore Announces New Steps Toward an Electronic Bill of Rights,” July 31, 1998, available at www.privacy2000.org/archives [hereinafter New Steps] 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 116 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp agement and Budget was given responsibility for coordination of privacy issues. 67 To assist in carrying out this task, I was named as Chief Counselor for Privacy, in OMB, in March, 1999. 68 Meanwhile, a largely separate debate had been occurring for the area of medical privacy. 69 Medical privacy proposals were extensively considered leading up to passage of the Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of 1996 (HIPAA). 70 HIPAA mandated new rules so that providers and insurance companies would shift to electronic medical records. There was widespread agreement that privacy and security protections should be created as part of this shift to electronic records. In HIPAA, Congress set itself a deadline of August, 1999 to write medical privacy legislation. If it did not do so, then the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) was required to promptly issue a medical privacy regulation. The HIPAA deadline contributed to a new peak of privacy policy activity in the period before and during consideration of GLB in 1999. HHS Secretary Donna Shalala, drawing on a large inter-agency process, announced the Administration’s recommendations for medical privacy legislation in the fall of 1997. 71 Vice President Gore announced medical privacy initia- 67. “OMB will be given responsibility for coordination of privacy issues, drawing on the expertise and resources of other government agencies. This will help improve the coordination of U.S. privacy policy, which cuts across the jurisdiction of many federal agencies.” Id. OMB had long maintained respon- sibility of overseeing agency implementation of the Privacy Act. 5 U.S.C. 552a(v) (2000). The change was that OMB would now have responsibility to coordinate privacy issues generally, including financial and medical privacy issues, and not simply oversight for federal systems of records under the Pri- vacy Act. 68. Robert O’Harrow, Jr., Clinton Names Counselor on Privacy, WASH. POST, Mar. 4, 1999, at E2. 69. The debate was “separate” in the sense of having different actors in- volved. The Department of Health and Human Services was the lead agency for medical privacy as opposed to the Department of Commerce and the inde- pendent agency FTC for Internet privacy. In the Senate, medical privacy was considered in the Health, Education, Labor, and Pensions Committee, while Internet privacy was in the Commerce, Science, and Transportation Commit- tee. In the House, medical privacy was principally considered in the Ways and Means Committee and one subcommittee of the Commerce Committee, while Internet issues were handled in a different subcommittee of the Commerce Committee. 70. Health Insurance Portability and Accountability Act of 1996, Pub. L. 104-191. 71. See Shalala Urges Congress to Protect Americans’ Personal Medical Records, (Sept. 11, 1997), available at http://www.hhs.gov/news.press/ 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 117 tives in the summer of 1998, and called for strong medical pri- vacy legislation. 72 The Congressional committees responsible for health care worked on numerous legislative proposals, try- ing in vain to pass legislation before HHS gained regulatory authority in August, 1999. 73 As it be- came increasingly clear that Congress was unlikely to act, the Administration prepared a detailed proposed medical privacy regulation. President Clinton announced the proposed rule in an Oval Office ceremony on October 31, 1999, less than two weeks before he signed GLB. The Internet privacy and medical records debates helped create the affirmative arguments for why privacy protections would be appropriate as well for financial records. At the same time, the political context for GLB was being shaped by devel- opments in the European Union, the U.S. debate on encryption policy, and the so-called “Know Your Customer” rules. The European Union Data Protection Directive was rati- fied in 1995, with implementation scheduled for October, 1998. 74 The Directive requires harmonized and generally strict privacy protections within the fifteen member states of the European Union. Article 25 of the Directive said that personal information could be transferred to other countries only if they had “adequate” privacy protections. 75 Article 25 raised the pos- sibility that trade with Europe could be significantly disrupted if the United States was found to lack “adequate” protections. 76 Reasonable people can differ about the extent that the Di- rective pushed the United States toward passage of Title V or stricter privacy protections generally. In my view, the debates about the Directive at a minimum educated and sensitized a 1997pres/970911.html. 72. New Steps, supra note 66. For instance, the Vice President an- nounced that the Administration would not develop standards for unique health identifiers as called for by HIPAA, until and unless strong privacy pro- tections were in place. Id. 73. Health Care Policy: Congressional Roundup, 8 HEALTH L. REP. (BNA) No.42, at 1728 (Oct. 28 1999). 74. See generally SWIRE & LITAN, supra note 6. 75. Directive, Art. 25. Article 26 creates a number of exceptions that can permit transfers to countries that lack “adequate” protection. 76. Intensive discussions with the European Union, led on the United States side by David Aaron and Barbara Wellbery, eventually resulted in the spring of 2000 with a “safe harbor” agreement. Essentially, companies that agree to be bound by safe harbor privacy principles are allowed to share data freely between their European Union and U.S. operations. See safe harbor website, available at http://www.export.gov/safeharbor. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 118 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp greater range of U.S. policy officials to privacy issues. Aware- ness of the detailed privacy regulations in Europe made it eas- ier to imagine similar regulations in the United States and more difficult for industry to say that such regulations would be unworkable. 77 In the financial services area, the most publi- cized enforcement action in Europe was brought against Citi- bank, and policy discussions about the Directive foreshadowed the issues that arose in the GLB debates. 78 The debate about encryption policy brought fervor to the privacy issue while involving many members of Congress. 79 The legal issue at the heart of the debate was setting the terms under which encryption software and hardware could be ex- ported from the United States. Law enforcement and national security officials were concerned that criminals would deploy encryption domestically and that the United States would lose its ability to read messages that intelligence sources gathered from abroad. E-commerce companies supported strong encryp- tion as a necessary tool for securely conducting business trans- actions over the Internet. Encryption enthusiasts and privacy supporters entered the debate with passionate rhetoric about the importance of strong encryption to individual liberty on the Internet. 80 The Clinton Administration initially sided with the law en- forcement and national security position, supporting in 1993 the “Clipper chip” that would have facilitated government ac- cess to encrypted communications. 81 Encryption continued to be a hotly debated issue throughout 1998 and 1999. 82 In June, 1999—as the House was preparing to vote on the financial 77. DAVID VOGEL, TRADING UP: CONSUMER AND ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION IN A GLOBAL ECONOMY 259 (1995). 78. The Swire and Litan book about the Directive devoted a chapter spe- cifically to financial services privacy issues, and also examined a number of the specific situations that became exceptions under GLB § 502(e). SWIRE & LITAN, supra note 6, at ch. 4. 79. For a detailed and readable history of the encryption debate, see gen- erally PAUL LEVY, CRYPTO 1-2 (2000). 80. For a history of the policy debate from a civil liberties perspective, as well as current news and legislation, see, e.g., http://www.cdt.org/crypto. 81. John Mintz, U.S. Moves to Ensure Its Ability to Eavesdrop, WASH. POST, Apr. 17, 1993, at A9 (discussing announcement of the Clipper Chip); see also A. Michael Froomkin, The Metaphor is the Key: Cryptography, the Clipper Chip, and the Constitution, 143 U. PENN. L. REV. 709, 717-718 (1995) (discuss- ing legal issues implicated by Clipper Chip). 82. For a detailed chronology of the period, see http://www.cdt.org/ previ- ousheads/encryption.shtml. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 119 modernization bill—encryption privacy bills passed both the Senate and House Commerce Committees. 83 In September, 1999, as the financial modernization conference committee was deliberating, the White House announced a major shift on en- cryption in the direction of greater exports and privacy protec- tion. 84 The encryption debate, stretching over several years, culminated in literally hundreds of members of Congress an- nouncing their support for stronger encryption, and thus the greater privacy protections that would result. 85 Meanwhile, the “know your customer” rule brought new at- tention to issues of financial privacy. The regulation was pro- posed by federal banking regulators in late 1998 as part of the ongoing efforts to crack down on money laundering. 86 The rule used language that provoked a privacy alarm: As proposed, the regulation would require each bank to develop a program designed to determine the identity of its customers; deter- mine its customers’ sources of funds; determine the normal and ex- pected transactions of its customers; monitor account activity for transactions that are inconsistent with those normal and expected transactions; and report any transactions of its customers that are de- termined to be suspicious, in accordance with the [agency’s] existing suspicious activity reporting regulation. 87 In immediate response to the proposal, press accounts ap- peared describing the rule as “an Orwellian intrusion into Americans’ privacy.” 88 Opposition arose from a combination of 83. Id. 84. Press Release, The White House, Press Briefing by Deputy National Security Advisor Jim Steinberg, Attorney General Janet Reno, Deputy Secre- tary of Defense John Hamre, Under Secretary of Commerce Bill Reinsch, and Chief Counselor for Privacy at OMB Peter Swire, (Sept. 16, 1999), available at http://www.privacy2000.org/archive. “I’m here to underscore that today’s an- nouncement reflects the Clinton Administration’s full support for the use of encryption and other new technologies to provide privacy and security to law- abiding citizens in the digital age.” Remarks of Peter Swire. Id. 85. See, e.g., Joe Salkowski, Encryption Campaign Ends With a Triumph for Common Sense, CHI. TRIB., Sept. 27, 1999, § 4, at 6 (reporting that a major- ity of members of the House supported the House encryption privacy bill). 86. The discussion here draws on an analysis of money laundering laws and privacy, written in early 1999. Peter P. Swire, Financial Privacy and the Theory of High-Tech Government Surveillance, 77 WASH. U. L.Q. 461, 487-92 (1999). For an extremely detailed treatment of money laundering laws, see L. RICHARD FISCHER, THE LAW OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY ?? 4.01-4.13 (3d ed. 1991). 87. Know Your Customer Requirements, 63 Fed. Reg. 67524 (Dec. 7 1998) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 21). 88. Declan McCullagh, Banking with Big Brother, available at http://www.wired.com/news/print/0,1294,16749,00.html (last modified Dec. 10, 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 120 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp conservative, liberal, and libertarian groups, foreshadowing a coalition that emerged again in the GLB debates. 89 More than 200,000 comments rolled in, almost all of them negative. 90 Pri- vacy had become a mobilizing issue politically. The rule was retracted in March, 1999. 91 These five privacy debates—Internet privacy, medical re- cords, the European Directive, encryption, and know your cus- tomer—were thus all in full swing in early 1999 as Congress prepared to debate the financial modernization bill. Many in the financial services industry thought that the 1999 moderni- zation bill would closely resemble the 1998 bill that almost passed. These industry insiders had a difficult time under- standing how privacy suddenly became so important in the 1999 financial debates. For those who had been engaged in the other privacy debates, however, the question seemed differ- ent—why shouldn’t financial records, which most people con- sider very sensitive, be subject to privacy protections, too? C. THE POLICY CONTEXT IN 1999 FOR FINANCIAL PRIVACY In considering financial privacy legislation, one can start with some basic goals. A first goal, in a democracy, is to have the laws match the desires of the public. In the legislative de- bates, one important consideration was the widely held view that financial records contain sensitive personal information. Repeated polls have shown that Americans place financial in- formation in an especially sensitive category with medical re- cords and certain other information, such as gathering data on children surfing on-line. 92 In a democracy, there is a straight- 1998). 89. Id. Groups expressing opposition included the Free Congress Founda- tion, a conservative group, the Libertarian Party and American Civil Liberties Union, libertarian groups on the right and left, and the Electronic Privacy In- formation Center, a generally liberal group. In the GLB debates, generally conservative Republican Senator Richard Shelby and Representative Joe Bar- ton teamed with generally liberal Democrats such as Senator Richard Bryan and Representative Edward Markey to support stricter financial privacy pro- tections. Digest,WASH. POST, Nov. 11, 1999, at E1 (these four members of Congress introduce stricter financial privacy bill). 90. Robert O’Harrow, Jr., Disputed Bank Plan Dropped; Regulators Bow to Privacy Fears, WASH. POST, Mar. 24, 1999, at E1 (over 200,000 comments); Michael Kelly, Banking With Big Brother, WASH. POST, Feb. 3, 1999, at A17 (all but 12 comments to FDIC on the rule, out of 15,000, were negative). 91. O’Harrow, supra note 90. 92. A Gallup survey found that 84 % of respondents stated that the pri- vacy of personal financial information was “very important,” with personal 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 121 forward logic to providing stricter protections for information that citizens consider especially important. A second goal is to maximize the benefits of legislation. There is an efficiency argument for having stricter protections for sensitive data. 93 In the contract between an individual and a company, it is more efficient if the contract reflects what well- informed parties would agree to, if there were no costly hurdles to their reaching an agreement. Other things equal, individu- als will bargain for greater protection for more sensitive data. Individuals may be indifferent if marketers know which flavor of toothpaste they use, but may care considerably more if their psychiatric history or the history of every purchase they had ever made became widely available. It is likely efficient to set stricter default rules for sensitive medical and financial data than for toothpaste sales. A third goal is to minimize the costs of legislation. Some kinds of data sharing promote efficiency. One important exam- ple is the prevention of fraud. Lenders need accurate credit re- ports before they make loans, and credit card companies watch for out-of-pattern purchases that may indicate that a thief has stolen the credit card. A well-designed privacy regime would achieve the benefits of treating sensitive information carefully while permitting these desirable forms of information sharing. Where the benefits of privacy protection appear to out- weigh the costs, an additional question is how a legislative ap- proach would compare with alternative institutional ap- proaches. 94 In the privacy context, one hope has been that technological measures could protect individuals’ information without the need for legal protections. Perhaps encryption or other technical measures will mean that the only people who see the data are those that the individual chooses. I have ar- medical records next at 78 %. By contrast, only 39% of respondents considered it “very important” for employment history to be private and 30% for educa- tional records to be private. The Inst. for Health Freedom, Public Attitudes Towards Medical Privacy (Sept. 2000) available at http://www.forhealthfreedom.org/Gallupsurvey/IHF-Gallup.html. 93. For a more extended discussion of the efficiency argument, including discussion of typical market failures and government failures in privacy regu- lation, see Peter P. Swire, Markets, Self-Regulation, and Government En- forcement in the Protection of Personal Information, in U.S. Dept. of Com- merce, PRIVACY AND SELF-REGULATION IN THE INFORMATION AGE 3, 5-8 (1997) [hereinafter, Swire, Markets]. 94. On the importance of comparative institutional analysis, see generally NEAL K. KOMESAR, IMPERFECT ALTERNATIVES: CHOOSING INSTITUTIONS IN LAW, ECONOMICS, AND PUBLIC POLICY 1-50 (1994). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 122 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp gued elsewhere, however, that a purely technological approach will not work well for most personal financial data. 95 To give just one example, lenders will insist on seeing considerable fi- nancial data before trusting a borrower with a loan. We should thus expect that financial institutions will continue to gather considerable information about their customers, and the pri- vacy challenge will be who will get to see that information, on what terms. Another possible approach to consider is self-regulation, where industry creates the standards for privacy protection. How to choose between self-regulation and government rules is a complex question, with the answer varying with the circum- stances. 96 For financial services, several factors tipped the bal- ance toward a legislative approach. First, legislation is more generally appropriate for sensitive data where consumer con- cerns and potential harms from misuse are greater. Second, there was evidence that the banks were not performing well on self-regulation. A 1998 FTC report found that only sixteen per- cent of banks had any privacy notices or policies on their on- line web sites. 97 Third, the self-regulatory codes from bank in- dustry groups were at a very high level of generality, and there was considerable uncertainty about the extent to which these codes were improving actual practice. 98 Finally, having finan- cial regulatory agencies already in place made it easier institu- tionally to imagine an effective regulatory regime. For in- stance, bank examiners already had to check banks’ internal systems, so they could fairly readily check as well to see whether privacy and security rules were being followed. Given the weaknesses of technological or self-regulatory approaches, the case for a legislative approach became more compelling. That case was strengthened by two factors— 95. Peter P. Swire, The Uses and Limits of Financial Cryptography: A Law Professor’s Perspective, available at http://acs.ohio-state.edu/units/law/ swire.pscrypto.htm. 96. For my analysis of how to make this choice generally, see Swire, Mar- kets, supra note 93. 97. The statistics from the 1998 FTC report were: only 16% of all financial web sites surveyed have at least one “information practice disclosure.” Among sites that actively collect personal information, 17% had such a disclosure, and only 2% had a “Privacy Policy Notice.” FTC, Privacy Online: A Report to Con- gress, at 27 (1998) available at http://www.ftc.gov/reports/privacy3/ index.htm. 98. See generally CONSUMER BANKERS ASSOCIATION, FINANCIAL PRIVACY IN AMERICA: A REVIEW OF CONSUMER FINANCIAL SERVICES ISSUES (1998) (constituting a collection of financial privacy statements from the period). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 123 industry convergence and the newly increased level of detail in financial records. Convergence was a principal industry goal for financial modernization legislation. The 1933 Glass-Steagall Act 99 and subsequent legislation created legal barriers to combining the major financial companies that serve consumers, such as com- mercial banks, insurance companies, securities brokers, and mutual funds. Over time, loopholes developed so that some al- liances were permitted between commercial banks and other financial companies. 100 GLB swept away the remaining barriers to affiliation. As mentioned above, financial holding companies may now engage in any activity that regulators determine “to be financial in nature or incidental to such financial activity.” 101 By bringing together previously separate institutions, propo- nents of modernization hoped to achieve substantial benefits, such as one-stop shopping for consumers, the ability to create new products and lines of business, and diversification of risk for previously specialized sellers. 102 Those concerned about privacy, however, had a different perspective. They pointed out that privacy protections had been an essential component of medical system reform in HIPAA, as well as in the 1996 Telecommunications Act, which permitted convergence in the telecommunications industry. 103 There was both a political and policy logic to linking privacy with convergence. The political logic was that the best moment to create privacy protections, which industry opposed, was when industry badly wanted legislation to allow convergence, 99. Sections 20 and 32 of the Glass-Steagall Act, which were specifically repealed by the 1999 reform, were the key sections prohibiting combinations of commercial and investment banks. 12 U.S.C. §§ 78, 377 (repealed by Section 101(a)-(b) of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act). 100. For instance, “Section 20” affiliates allowed limited underwriting of securities through affiliates of commercial banks. Sec. Indus. Ass’n. v. Clarke, 885 F.2d 1034 (2 nd Cir. 1989). See generally JONATHAN R. MACEY & GEOFFREY P. MILLER, BANKING LAW AND REGULATION (1992) (presenting abundant cases eroding Glass-Steagall barriers). 101. Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999, Pub. L. No. 106-102 §103(a), 113 Stat. 1338, 1342 (1999) (to be codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1843(k)(1)(A)). 102. See generally ROBERT E. LITAN, WHAT SHOULD BANKS DO? 60-143 (1987) (presenting an insightful analysis of the advantages and disadvantages of convergence); but see Arthur E. Wilmarth, Jr., The Transformation of the U.S. Financial Services Industry, 1975-2000; Competition, Consolidation, and Increased Risks, U. ILL. L. REV. (forthcoming, 2002) (expressing skepticism about the likelihood of these benefits being realized). 103. Telecommunications Act, P.L. 104-104, at Sec. 222, enacted in 1996. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 124 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp which industry favored. 104 It would be far more difficult to cre- ate legislative momentum for privacy except when industry also wanted a bill. The policy logic was that convergence would result in larger enterprises as well as mergers of firms that previously were in separate lines of business. Larger enter- prises would mean larger databases, with greater privacy risk. Mergers of separate industries would mean that consumers who gave information to a company in one sector would now have that data shared with different sectors—the sort of secon- dary use that fair information practices generally forbid unless there is customer consent. The newly increased level of detail in financial databases provided another important argument in favor of privacy pro- tection. The contrast with the 1970 Fair Credit Reporting Act had become stark. A credit report, for instance, might show that an individual had borrowed up to a $10,000 credit limit, and had once paid thirty days late. By 1999, by contrast, elec- tronic financial databases operated at the level of each transac- tion rather than the summary level. As I have discussed else- where in detail, 105 there are strong trends toward having permanent, electronic, and searchable records of individual consumer transactions. Purchases are shifting from cash and checks, which do not usually go into searchable databases, to much greater reliance on credit and debit cards, which gener- ally do. Consumers have incentives, such as frequent-flyer programs, to use credit and debit cards. Such cards have be- come the standard payment mechanism for the growing world of Internet purchases. And less affluent Americans are in- creasingly receiving government benefits through smart cards and other electronic-based systems. These changes create a detailed, lifetime record of a large and growing fraction of individuals’ purchases. Under Secre- tary of the Treasury Gary Gensler explained the problem in his testimony in the summer of 1999: A generation ago, financial privacy meant keeping private your sal- ary, your bank balances, and your net worth. Today, financial privacy means keeping secret your entire way of life. . . . The credit card re- cords of 1999 . . . can list each and every purchase ever made by that 104. I heard this rationale articulated most clearly by Rep. Edward Markey, who was unusual among members of Congress in having been active on HIPAA, the Telecommunications Act, and GLB. 105. Peter P. Swire, Financial Privacy and the Theory of High-Tech Gov- ernment Surveillance, in BROOKINGS-WHARTON PAPERS ON FINANCIAL SERVICES 391-442 (Robert E. Litan et al. eds.) (1999). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 125 customer, sorted by date, location, and other details. Furthermore, if credit card companies work together with merchants, then the level of detail can become even more refined—each dish ordered at a restau- rant or each book title bought at a store. 106 This unprecedented level of detail, combined with the pos- sibility of comprehensive matching with other merchant data- bases, is a distinctive feature of financial records. In response to this distinctive problem, there was a strong argument for a distinctive legal regime to address the problem. D. THE 1999 LEGISLATIVE HISTORY Early in 1999, the pressure to protect financial privacy was not easy to detect. Financial modernization had nearly passed at the end of 1998, only to get hung up when the Administra- tion and Congressional Republicans could not agree on the Community Reinvestment Act and the role of the Treasury De- partment in financial regulation. 107 The House and Senate Banking Committees both passed financial modernization bills in March, with no significant privacy provisions. 108 The situation changed shortly thereafter. On May 4, President Clinton gave what I believe was the first presidential address in history dedicated to privacy protection. 109 The President stated that financial data was sensitive information deserving of legal protection, and consumers should have an opt-out choice before data is shared with affiliates or third par- ties. Two days later, the Senate adopted some modest privacy provisions aimed at preventing “pretext calling,” the fraudulent procurement of personal financial information. 110 Attention to privacy climbed another notch on June 7, when lead bank regulator Jerry Hawke used unusually strong language in criticizing banks’ privacy practices. 111 In a speech 106. See Testimony of Under Secretary of the Treasury Gary Gensler, at http://www.privacy2000.org/archives/Treasury_6-14-00Gensler_testimony% 20_on_hr4585.htm (last visited Mar. 11, 2002). 107. Dean Anason, Supporters of Reform Bill Rally for a Rematch, AM. BANKER, Oct. 23, 1998, at 1. 108. Stephen Labaton, Congress Acts to Alter Rules on Banking, N.Y. TIMES, Mar. 5, 1999, at C4 (describing both bills without mentioning privacy). 109. Remarks Announcing the Financial Privacy and Consumer Protection Initiative, I PUB. PAPERS 682 (May 4, 1999) available at www.privacy2000.org/archives (last checked Mar. 17, 2002). 110. R. Christian Bruce, Senate Clears Financial Modernization Bill, De- feating Operating Subsidiary Amendment, BNA BANKING REP., May 10, 1999, at 825. 111. Remarks by John D. Hawke, Jr., Comptroller of the Currency, before a 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 126 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp to industry, Hawke objected to practices “that are at least seamy, if not downright unfair and deceptive.” 112 He particu- larly condemned the sale of customer financial information to telemarketing firms. Two days later, Minnesota Attorney Gen- eral Mike Hatch announced a lawsuit against U.S. Bank for particularly egregious sales of such information. According to the complaint, U.S. Bank sold account numbers, Social Security numbers, and other detailed information to the marketing firm Member Works. 113 Member Works asked consumers on the phone if they were interested in saving money on dental or health plans. If the consumer said yes, then Member Works would send a postcard stating that the consumer had thirty days to opt out of the plan. If the consumer did not opt out, then Member Works would automatically withdraw money from the consumer’s U.S. Bank account. The privacy policy of U.S. Bank, a major financial firm, said it would strive to main- tain customer confidentiality. 114 It gave no indication that any data was supplied to telemarketers or other outside firms. The next day, the House Commerce Committee reacted to this news. 115 The key action occurred during a discussion of an amendment offered by Rep. Edward Markey, a liberal Democ- rat who personally supported a strict opt-in before sharing with third parties or affiliates. Markey’s amendment was similar to President Clinton’s position, with opt-out before sharing with third parties or affiliates. The amendment also included lan- guage addressed to the U.S. Bank situation, barring release of bank account numbers to telemarketers. In a remarkable se- quence, conservative Republican Joseph Barton expressed his anger at receiving a Victoria’s Secret catalogue at his Washing- Conference Sponsored by the Consumer Bankers Association (June 7, 1999). 112. Id. 113. U.S. Bank provided the following information about its customers: name, address, telephone numbers . . ., gender, marital status, home- ownership status, occupation, checking account number, credit card number, Social Security number, birth date, account open date, aver- age account balance, account frequency information, credit limit, credit insurance status, year to date finance charges, automated transactions authorized, credit card type and brand, number of credit cards, cash advance amount, behavior score, bankruptcy score, date of last payment, amount of last payment, date of last statement, and statement balance. Minnesota Attorney General Hatch Sues U.S. Bank for Disclosing Customers’ Private Information to Telemarketer, PR NEWSWIRE, June 9, 1999. 114. Id. 115. The account here is based on my own recollection and corroboration from others who attended the House Commerce Committee markup. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 127 ton apartment. He said that his address had been supplied by his credit card company, and stated his displeasure of what his wife back home in Texas would think of his perusing such a catalogue when he was in Washington. Democratic Represen- tative Anna Eshoo said that someone had stolen her credit card number the previous year, and described how difficult it was to clear up this instance of identity theft. Ranking Democrat John Dingell suggested to his colleagues that their opponents in the next election would find it useful to leaf through the members’ personal financial records. Suddenly, the Markey amendment was approved in a voice vote. Industry lobbyists were in shock. Privacy advocates were surprised and de- lighted. 116 The House Commerce Committee vote redefined the pri- vacy debate for the year. The Administration, most Congres- sional Democrats, and a few Republicans tried to retain the privacy protections that the Commerce Committee had ap- proved. Most Congressional Republicans worked with industry to draft more limited protections. At the next step, the Republi- can-controlled House Rules Committee eliminated the privacy protections approved by the Commerce Committee. 117 On the House floor, the privacy issue, which had been practically in- visible a few months earlier, was the predominant topic of de- bate. On a procedural vote, the House rejected a Democratic proposal to reinstate the House Commerce version. 118 The 116. The discussion here is primarily intended to describe the legislative history of GLB rather than to develop a theory of the legislative process. Nonetheless, the House Commerce Committee mark-up poses something of a puzzle for public choice theorists who expect a politically mobilized industry, such as the financial services industry, to succeed against those supporting the general public’s diffuse interest in privacy protection. 117. U.S. House Clears Way to Debate on Bank Overhaul Bill, BLOMBERG NEWS, July 1, 1999. 118. For the final House vote, the Clinton Administration supported the privacy provisions ultimately included in the House bill while calling for the additional protections discussed in the President’s speech in May: The President has stated the importance of adopting protections to ensure the privacy of consumers’ financial records. Adoption of the amendment to be considered by the House would improve the bill by including new privacy protections, although it does not address all of the issues involved. The Administration will continue to pursue addi- tional protections. The White House, Statement of Administration Position, July 1, 1999, avail- able at www.privacy2000.org/archives. The White House objected to a provision that would have governed medi- cal information in financial holding companies: 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 128 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp House then, by a nearly unanimous vote, approved an amend- ment that required an opt-out for transfers to third parties. 119 Even those who had opposed the stricter privacy version spoke at length about the importance of keeping the bill’s existing privacy protections, 120 confirming the issue’s importance as the House and Senate entered a conference to reconcile their bills. Negotiations in the conference committee lasted from early July to October. As the Republican committee chairmen neared a compromise proposal, the Administration for the first time included privacy as a basis for vetoing the bill if protec- tions were not strict enough. 121 The committee chairmen then released their “chairmen’s mark,” which was weaker on privacy than the version passed in the House. 122 As negotiations on privacy and other issues continued, the conference committee made the chairmen’s proposal stricter on privacy in three re- The Administration also has serious concerns about the provisions on medical privacy in this financial services legislation. Unfortunately, the current approach would preempt important existing protections and does not reflect extensive legislative work that has already been done on this complex issue. The Administration thus supports strik- ing the medical privacy provisions, and pursuing medical privacy in other fora. Id. The medical privacy provision was eliminated in the GLB conference. President Clinton’s 2000 legislative proposal would have addressed the issue of medical information that is held by financial holding companies but not cov- ered by the HIPAA medical privacy protections. Consumer Financial Privacy Act, H.R. 4380, 106th Cong; Financial Information Privacy Protection Act of 2000, S. 2513, 106th Cong. The House Banking Committee approved such leg- islation in 2000, but the bill did not progress further. Medical Financial Pri- vacy Protection Act, H.R. 4585, 102d Cong. § 2 (2000). The current legality of sharing medical data among affiliates, such as a life insurance company send- ing medical information to a lending affiliate, remains a possible impetus for additional privacy legislation that would affect financial institutions. 119. House Passes Financial Services Bill by Large Margin after Procedural Skirmish, BNA BANKING REPORT, July 5, 1999, at 5. 120. For instance, Republican Rep. Marge Roukema said about the amendment: “This gives us more privacy than under any law that we have ever had. This is a giant step in the right direction.” Id. 121. Barbara A. Rehm, Key Disputes Still Unresolved as Financial Reform Votes Near, AM. BANKER, Oct. 11, 1999 at 1 (describing veto threat by White House Chief of Staff John Podesta). The Clinton Administration had repeat- edly threatened to veto the bill on other grounds, but the inclusion of privacy in this veto letter was evidence of the increased importance of the issue in the course of the year. The letter’s other bases for a possible veto concerned the allocation of regulatory authority between the Treasury Department and the Federal Reserve, the Community Reinvestment Act, and retaining restrictions on the ability of depository institutions to affiliate with nonfinancial firms. 122. Dean Anason, GOP Reform Compromise Draws New Veto Threat, AM. BANKER, Oct. 13, 1999, at 1. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 129 spects: the more protective House version mostly replaced the chairmen’s mark; the bill required notice for transfers to affili- ates, and not just to third parties; and the bill specifically pro- vided that states can offer stricter privacy protections than the federal floor. 123 Stricter privacy amendments were rejected by the conference committee. After a few more days of grueling negotiations on other issues, the Administration and Congres- sional leaders reached agreement on October 22. President Clinton signed the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act on November 12, praising the legislation in general but calling for stricter pri- vacy legislation in the future. 124 E. DEVELOPMENTS SINCE 1999 At the signing of GLB, President Clinton called on the Treasury Department, the National Economic Council, and the Office of Management and Budget to prepare new legislation to complete the financial privacy protections begun in GLB. 123. For descriptions of the final negotiations, see Daniel J. Parks, Finan- cial Services Bill In the Final Stretch, CQ WEEKLY, Oct. 23, 1999, at 2498; Kathleen Day, Banking Accord Likely to Be Law, WASH. POST, Oct. 23, 1999, at A1. 124. In his signing statement, President Clinton said: “Without restraining the economic potential of new business arrangements, I want to make sure that every family has meaningful choices about how their personal informa- tion will be shared within corporate conglomerates. We can’t allow new oppor- tunities to erode old and fundamental rights.” Remarks of President William J. Clinton, Nov. 12, 1999, available at www.privacy2000.org/archives. Privacy advocates and some members of Congress criticized the Admini- stration for supporting the legislation even though it fell short of the protec- tions that President Clinton supported in his speech in May. See Parks, supra note 123 (describing the criticisms). Without going into the nature of Admini- stration deliberations on this topic, here are a few observations concerning the decision not to veto the bill on privacy grounds. First, the financial moderni- zation bill was a major bill, both in its size (hundreds of pages) and in its im- portance in reshaping the structure of the financial industry set forth by the Glass-Steagall Act in 1933. The Administration was clearly on record in sup- port of the basic principles of financial modernization. Second, the other is- sues involved in negotiations in the final days had been announced Admini- stration priorities long before President Clinton’s first speech on financial privacy in May, 1999. Third, privacy was intensively negotiated in the weeks leading up to release of the chairmen’s mark. The final bill contained signifi- cant strengthening of privacy compared the chairmen’s mark, especially by permitting states to enact stricter privacy laws, and it is not clear how readily additional privacy protections could have been negotiated into the final bill. Fourth, it is plausible that additional privacy protections may be included in future financial services bills. In the context of these considerations, perhaps it is easier for those studying the privacy issue to understand the Administra- tion decision to sign GLB despite the weaknesses in privacy protection. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 130 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp President Clinton proposed the Consumer Financial Privacy Act (CFPA) in April. 125 With financial modernization now en- acted, the CFPA gave the Administration an opportunity to present its views about how to protect financial privacy while gaining the benefits of technology, competition, and innovation in financial services. 126 Among other provisions, the CFPA called for an opt-out for affiliate sharing. It required an opt-in for sharing of medical information within a financial holding company. It also required an opt-in for transfer of the “per- sonal spending habits” of individuals, essentially the list of every purchase made by an individual through a checking ac- count, credit card, or similar instrument. Proposal of the CFPA helped spur legislative activity in 2000 on financial privacy. The House Banking Committee passed a bill that included much of the President’s proposed language, but limited to the sharing of medical information within a holding company. 127 In the Senate Banking Commit- tee, a coalition of Republican Senator Richard Shelby and committee Democrats created a situation where the committee could act on other matters only if financial privacy amend- ments were included. 128 Although no financial privacy legisla- tion reached the House or Senate floor in 2000 or 2001, there has been a steady stream of proposed bills. For instance, the new Democratic Chairman of the Senate Banking Committee, Paul Sarbanes, re-introduced the Clinton Administration pro- posal in 2001 as his proposed basis for additional financial pri- vacy protections. 129 125. See Commencement Address at Eastern Michigan University, Ypsi- lanti, Michigan, I PUB. PAPERS 794, 796 (Apr. 30, 2000) (presenting CFPA), available at www.privacy2000.org/archives; see also The White House, Office of the Press Secretary, Clinton-Gore Plan to Enhance Consumers’ Financial Privacy: Protecting Core Values in the Information Age, Apr. 30, 2000, avail- able at www.privacy2000.org/archives; The White House, Office of the Press Secretary, Press Background Briefing by Senior Administration Officials on Financial Privacy, available at www.privacy2000.org/archives. The bill was introduced in the House as H.R. 4380 and in the Senate as S. 2513. 126. The Administration position was explained in Testimony of Treasury Under Secretary Gary Gensler before the House Committee on Banking and Financial Services, June 14, 2000, available at www.privacy2000.org/archives. 127. See H.R. 4585 The Medical Financial Privacy Protection Act :Hearing Before the House Comm. on Banking and Financial Services, 106th Cong. 2 (2000) (statement of Jim Leach, Chairman, House Comm. on Banking and Fi- nancial Services). 128. Information on file with author. 129. Financial Information Privacy Protection Act of 2001, S. 30, 107th Cong (2001). Other financial privacy bills were introduced by Senator Shelby 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 131 On the regulatory front, the group of seven regulatory agencies worked under the tight six-month deadline set in GLB to promulgate a proposed and final regulation. 130 The seven regulations were very similar to each other and in general closely tracked the statutory language in GLB. The most con- troversial aspect of the regulations was the handling of cus- tomer lists. After soliciting comments in the proposed rules, the agencies decided that a customer list—the name and ad- dress of a customer together with the fact that the individual was the customer of a specific financial institution—should in- deed be covered by the opt-out and other provisions of GLB. This agency decision was upheld in court as a valid statutory interpretation. 131 Of perhaps greater long-term significance, the federal courts have upheld the interpretation against First Amendment challenge, holding that there was no impermissi- ble limit on speech created by the statutory opt-out require- ment. 132 Perhaps the other most important developments for finan- cial privacy have come at the state level. Vermont, Connecti- cut, and Alaska had opt-in laws before 1999, 133 and numerous similar bills were introduced in other states in 2000 and 2001. 134 Most prominently, a sweeping financial privacy bill came close to passage in California. 135 Privacy advocates have praised these state initiatives as an important way to raise the privacy standards in the financial services sector. Industry has expressed concern about the need to defend against legislative initiatives in the fifty states, and has increasingly called for and Congressman Markey. Freedom from Behavioral Profiling Act of 2000, S. 536, 107th Cong. (2001); Consumer’s Right to Financial Privacy Act, H.R. 2720, 107th Cong. (2001). 130. The seven agencies are the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Federal Reserve Board, the Federal Trade Commission, the National Credit Union Agency, the Office of Comptroller of the Currency, and the Securities and Exchange Commission. State insurance regulators have been in the proc- ess of implementing the model rule issued by the National Association of In- surance Commissioners. 131. Indiv. Reference Serv. Group, Inc. v. FTC, 145 F.Supp.2d 6 (D.D.C. 2001). 132. Id. 133. Sarah MacDonald, Vermont’s Tough Opt-In Privacy Law Could Be Model for Other States, AM. BANKER, July 6, 2000, at 1. 134. See the survey of proposed state laws in the annual survey by the Pri- vacy & Information Law Report. 135. Financial Institutions: Strict Privacy Bill Fails in California; Preda- tory Lending Legislation Gains Approval, BANKING DAILY (BNA), Sept. 21, 2001, at http://www.bna.com. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 132 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp federal preemption of stricter state laws. The Clinton Admini- stration position, for both financial and medical privacy, was that it may be appropriate to have federal preemption, but only if sufficiently strict standards were established at the federal level. III. SHARING WITH THIRD PARTIES AND AFFILIATES With the foregoing history in mind, we are prepared to look at the contentious issue of when consumers should have a choice before their financial data is shared with other organiza- tions. Part III of this Article first looks at the “formal” and “functional” approaches a regulatory system can take toward this issue. It then examines the joint marketing exception un- der FLB, which too often allows sharing with outside entities without consumer choice. It concludes by suggesting options for how to create appropriate rules to govern sharing of data with affiliated companies. A. FORMAL AND FUNCTIONAL APPROACHES FOR DEFINING SECONDARY USE Under the fair information practices discussed in Part I, a key issue is how to create an administrable regulatory system that defines the permissible purposes for sharing of personal data. One approach is functional—define in the regulations which purposes are compatible. The other basic approach is formal—define some legal boundary within which use is per- mitted but beyond which choice is required. Title V of GLB largely adopted the latter approach, although the analysis here suggests that a more functional approach may instead be ap- propriate. In implementing a formal approach, the GLB debates fo- cused on three possibilities. The first possibility was to require choice for affiliate sharing. Privacy advocates and the Clinton Administration proposed that information could be used within one corporation, such as a bank, but choice would be requested upon transfer to a separate corporation, including affiliates of the bank. 136 The second possibility, partly implemented by GLB, was that information could be used within a financial holding company, but choice would be required upon transfer to 136. Privacy advocates generally supported having opt-in for transfers to affiliates and third parties, while the Clinton Administration supported an opt-out choice. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 133 a non-affiliated corporation (a “third party”). The third possi- bility, supported by those opposed to privacy regulation, was to allow transfers to third parties without any choice requirement. The case for the formal approach is strongest if two condi- tions are met. The first condition is that the formal boundary is well defined, so that regulators and regulated companies can agree when compliance is required. A well-defined boundary will reduce regulatory costs and promote certainty. At least in many instances, the formal boundaries adopted for financial privacy in GLB satisfy this condition. It is generally straight- forward to determine when data moves from one corporation to another. The regulatory system has reasons to define and po- lice this boundary, such as where the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency’s supervision of a national bank ends and the Federal Reserve’s supervision of a state bank begins. It is simi- larly straightforward in most instances to determine whether a company is an affiliate of a financial institution or else an unaf- filiated third party. The Federal Reserve has extensive experi- ence in administering when a holding company “controls” a corporation so that the corporation is considered part of the holding company. 137 A formal approach is also desirable to the extent that the formal boundary is a good proxy for the underlying purposes of the regulation. To illustrate, suppose that all transfers within a bank were considered a primary use, and all transfers to other corporations were considered secondary uses. If this were true, then the corporate boundary would be an ideal proxy for defining uses that are compatible with the original use. On the other hand, one might find that many uses within a bank were unrelated to the original purposes of processing, while many transfers to other companies were in fact compatible with the original purposes. If the true state of affairs resembles this lat- ter scenario, then the corporate boundary would be a bad ap- proximation of when the individual should have a choice about new uses of the data. The benefits of formal boundaries—transfers to a separate corporation or an unaffiliated third party—will thus largely de- pend on whether the formal boundaries accurately distinguish 137. The statute, 12 U.S.C. § 1841(a), provides three conditions for testing control over a bank: (1) owning, controlling, or having the power to vote 25 percent of any class of voting securities; (2) controlling the election of a major- ity of the board of directors; and (3) exercising a direct or indirect controlling influence over the institutions management policies. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 134 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp between primary and secondary uses. To the extent that the boundaries do not supply an accurate distinction, then it be- comes more important to explore the possibility of a functional approach, where the regulatory attention more explicitly ad- dresses whether a particular use is compatible with the original use of the data or is otherwise desirable. B. THE JOINT MARKETING EXCEPTION GLB embodies the basic principle that transfers to unaf- filiated third parties constitute secondary use. Choice should be required before such transfers are made. I believe that this principle makes sense and that transfers to third parties vio- late most consumers’ expectations. Customers of a bank don’t expect the details of their transactions to be made available to their employers, neighbors, or business competitors. They don’t expect outside companies to get detailed information about their financial activities or purchasing habits. For data this de- tailed and sensitive, it makes sense to have legal guarantees that those outside of the bank’s corporate family do not have access to the data unless the customer has at least had a chance to say no. 1. Defining the Scope of the Problem Some transfers to unaffiliated third parties are sensible and are properly part of GLB. For instance, Section 502(b)(2) contains a provision that allows a financial institution to act as principal and have another company act as its agent “to per- form services for or function[] on behalf of the financial institu- tion, including marketing of the financial institution’s own products or services.” 138 Solid efficiency reasons support this rule. A principal should be able to choose whether to hire em- ployees or an independent contractor to do a task, such as print checks for a bank. Otherwise, the privacy rules could distort economic decisions about how to structure the business. If a bank could not hire an independent contractor, for instance, it might have to create an inefficient in-house check printing ca- pability. This sort of permission to hire independent contrac- tors is a standard feature of data protection laws, including the 138. Gramm-Leach-Bliley act [GLB] Pub. L. 106-102, § 502(b)(2), 113 Stat. 1437 (1999) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 6802(b)(2) (2001)). The same language was retained in the Clinton Administration proposal in 2000. H.R. 4380 § 10. Other exceptions that permit transfer to third parties without customer choice are contained in Section 502(e) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 6802(e) (2001)). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 135 European Union Data Protection Directive. 139 The accompany- ing safeguards, under both GLB and the Directive, are that the agent should act on behalf of the principal and the agent should assure the confidentiality of data it receives. 140 Another part of Section 502(b)(2), though, contains lan- guage that permits a large amount of secondary use. The “joint marketing exception” allows an unaffiliated third party to re- ceive data from one or more financial institutions and use the data for its own marketing purposes. 141 The statute provides only limited safeguards. The third party must be a “financial institution,” although the scope of activities that can qualify as “financial” is very broad under the new law. 142 There must be notice to customers that such transfers may occur, and the third party must contractually promise to maintain the confi- dentiality of such information. 143 One objectionable aspect of the joint marketing exception is that it was passed as a “bait and switch”—sold as one thing but in fact another. Essentially, the exception was justified as a way to solve certain problems for small banks. In practice, the exception has become a much broader tool, used intensively by the largest financial institutions. Based on press reports and my own participation in the legislative process in 1999, the joint marketing exception was primarily discussed in a single context. A large bank, such as Citibank, might offer a wide ar- 139. The Directive uses the term “controller” to refer to the principal, and the term “processor” to refer to the agent. Article 16 of the Directive states that the processor “must not process [personal data] except on instructions from the controller.” Article 17 sets forth related requirements, such as that a processor have a written contract and that the processor “shall act only on in- structions from the controller.” 140. Id. For principal/agent relationships under section 502(b)(2), the ser- vices performed by the agent are “on behalf of” the principal, the financial in- stitution “fully discloses the providing of such information and enters into a contractual agreement with the third party that requires the third party to maintain the confidentiality of such information.” 141. The statute allows sharing of data for “financial products or services offered pursuant to joint agreements between two or more financial institu- tions . . . .” 15 U.S.C. § 6802(b)(2). The financial institution that receives the data must itself comply with the GLB privacy requirements. Id. 142. Under the new law, a financial holding company may engage in any activity that is determined to be “financial in nature or incidental to such fi- nancial activity.” GLB, Pub. L. 106-102, § 103(a), 113 Stat. 1342-43 (as codi- fied at 12 U.S.C. § 1843(k)(1)(A)). It may also engage in additional activities that are “complementary to a financial activity” where there is no substantial risk to safety and soundness. 12 U.S.C. § 1843(k)(1)(B). 143. 15 U.S.C. § 6802(b)(2). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 136 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp ray of products with the Citi label. The products are often sup- plied by affiliated companies—insurance from one affiliate, mu- tual funds from another, and other products from dozens or hundreds of other affiliates. Customers of Citibank might see the “Citi” label on this range of products and never even realize that the products were coming from separate, affiliated corpo- rations. The business practices of small financial institutions, how- ever, are often different. The Smallville National Bank might also offer its customers a range of products with the “Small- ville” label. The difference is that the insurance might be un- derwritten by a non-affiliated outside company, and the mutual funds might be sold and managed by a different outside com- pany. Direct marketing might come directly from the insur- ance or mutual fund company, using the Smallville Bank’s cus- tomer list. Sales might also be made in the bank branch, with the customer representative offering the outside companies’ products with the Smallville label. When customers received the solicitation, they would be reassured by the Smallville Bank’s name on the product, and the Smallville Bank would build goodwill with the customer. In the absence of such an ar- rangement, the Smallville Bank would face the risk of turning its customers over to large and potentially full-service competi- tors, and so might decide not to offer the products at all. Looking to the legislative history, the joint marketing ex- ception did not exist when the House of Representatives passed its bill in June 1999. 144 Opt-out was required for third parties, but no opt-out applied to affiliates. As one lobbyist explained at the time: “If you’re a Citigroup, which has everything under one umbrella, you can share that information and market to your customer without giving an opt-out.” 145 Under the House bill, though, “small banks and thrifts that want to achieve syn- ergies with outside insurance or securities firms [would] have to notify their customers and let them block any information sharing.” 146 The joint marketing provision was added in nego- tiations between the House and Senate. When the provision was approved, press reports underscored that it was intended to help small banks, allowing them to offer services on a par 144. See H.R. 10, 106th Cong. (1999). 145. Scott Barancik, In the House, Banks Dodge Bullet on Privacy Limits, AM. BANKER, June 28, 1999, at 1 (quoting unidentified lobbyist). 146. Id. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 137 with large banks. 147 Today, the joint marketing provision is used far beyond the small banks. Industry giants such as Chase include joint mar- keting notices in their privacy policies. 148 A study by the Cen- ter for Democracy and Technology in the summer of 2000 sur- veyed 100 top on-line financial institutions. Forty-four of the institutions said they did not share information with outside parties as defined by GLB, and thus did not offer any GLB opt- out. Yet two-third of these (30) gave notice that they reserved the right to share information with joint marketing partners. 149 The credit card issued for the Target retail stores illus- trates the deployment of the joint marketing provision by large companies as well as the large range of secondary uses permit- ted under that provision. 150 In the joint marketing part of the privacy policy, the bank that issues the credit card says “[w]e may partner with other [financial institutions] . . . to market products or services jointly. We may need to share the follow- ing information: Identification and contact information (for ex- ample, your name, address, and telephone number). Account transaction and experience information (for example, your bal- ance, purchase, and payment history).” 151 This privacy policy illustrates a two-way street for retailing and financial information. Under this policy, outside financial companies can apparently receive full details about what an individual has purchased at Target and its affiliated operations such as Marshall Fields, catalog operations, and web sites. 152 147. Dean Anason, GOP Reform Compromise Draws New Veto Threat, AM. BANKER, Oct. 13, 1999, at 1 (“Broadening exceptions to help small banks, fi- nancial institutions that have joint marketing agreements with nonbanks would not have to give customers an opt-out option.”); see also Community Bankers Oppose H.R. 10 Privacy Clause, Call for ‘Parity,’ CREDIT RISK MGMT. REPORT, July 26, 1999 (supporting the exception to create parity for small banks, because they “outsource a variety of functions that larger organizations perform in-house.”). 148. See CHASE, CHASE PRIVACY POLICY (2002), at http://www.chase.com (last visited Mar. 8, 2002)). 149. CENTER FOR DEMOCRACY & TECHNOLOGY, ONLINE BANKING PRIVACY: A SLOW, CONFUSING START TO GIVING CUSTOMERS CONTROL OVER THEIR INFORMATION 2 (2000), available at http://www.cdt.org (Aug. 29, 2001). 150. See RETAILERS NATIONAL BANK, RETALIERS NATIONAL BANK PRIVACY POLICY (2002), at http://www.target.com/common/financialservices/retailers_ national_bank_privacy_policy.jhtr (last visited Mar. 8, 2002). 151. Id. 152. The policy of the Retailers National Bank, which issues the credit card, lists retail companies such as Target, Marshall Field’s, and Mervyn’s. It lists web sites including target.direct and associated sites. It lists catalogs 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 138 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp Similarly, outside financial institutions can provide detailed in- formation to Target. For instance, an outside bank or credit card company could provide a list of every check or credit card purchase an individual had made in the past year, in order to assist Target in targeting that customer for retail sales. Under this policy, a retail use readily can become a use in a tradi- tional financial setting such as a bank or insurance company. A financial use, such as operating a credit card or making a loan, can readily become a use in a retail setting on-line, through a catalogue or in a physical store. Secondary uses abound. 153 The Target example suggests the weakness of the statutory safeguards built into the joint marketing exception. First, the requirement that the sharing be with a “financial institution” does not keep the data within a tight orbit of activities that an ordinary person would think of as “financial” in nature. GLB’s broad definition of financial institution means that even activi- ties that are “incidental” or “complementary” to a financial ac- tivity can be carried out by a financial institution. 154 Second, the notice requirement is vague and gives customers little in- formation about the scope or type of the data sharing. Joint marketing disclosures typically do not list the quantity or names of the marketing partners. They often include comfort- ing language that states that data will only be shared with carefully selected partners, but this language likely creates few or no legal limits on where the data can go. 155 Third, the qual- ity of the required confidentiality contracts is suspect. The chief problem is that the marketing partner, who receives the data for joint marketing purposes, can then re-use the same data for any other purpose. The joint marketing partner is not limited to acting as an agent, on behalf of the principal that such as Signals, Wireless, and Seasons, and associated web sites. Id. 153. For a detailed examination of how GLB governs co-branding and simi- lar arrangements, see L. Richard Fischer & Oliver I. Ireland, Living with the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Privacy Rules—Private Labels, Co-Brand, Agent Bank and Other Credit Partnerships, 2 PRIVACY & INFO. LAW REPORT, 1, 1 (2001). 154. 12 U.S.C. 1843(k) (2000). Most of these non-traditional “financial in- stitutions” are regulated by the Federal Trade Commission. For regulations defining the scope of that term, see supra note 32. 155. For instance, the Target policy says: “We carefully select [our financial institution partners] to be sure they have procedures in place to protect your privacy.” RETAILERS NATIONAL BANK, supra note 150 . This language would apparently support selection of a large number of partners, and proving a vio- lation of this “careful selection” language would be highly difficult. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 139 discloses the data. 156 The problem of having the recipient act as a principal is compounded by GLB Section 502(c), which is entitled “Limits on reuse of information.” As actually written, Section 502(c) governs only subsequent disclosures to addi- tional companies, and does not place any limits on subsequent uses of the data by a company that has already received the data. 157 2. Responses to the joint marketing issue In light of the weak existing safeguards under the joint marketing exception, new legislation should eliminate the ex- ception or reduce its scope considerably. I will discuss elimi- nating the exception and then discuss an alternative that al- lows joint marketing to continue only for small financial institutions. The Consumer Financial Privacy Act of 2000 proposed eliminating the exception entirely. 158 The CFPA retained the ability to use third parties as agents who act on behalf of a principal, and it retained the other GLB exceptions that allow transfers of data that are necessary to complete a transaction and for other priority uses. 159 I believe there is a strong case for adopting this position and eliminating the exception. Cus- tomers of one financial institution do not and should not expect that their personal data will be transferred to any other finan- cial institution in the economy, with no choice in the matter. The ability of the recipient institution to re-use the data for any 156. As discussed, supra, text accompanying note 140, an agent can receive data and act “on behalf of” a principal. GLB 502(b)(2), 113 Stat. at 1338, 1437. The “on behalf of” requirement does not apply to joint marketing partners, who can use the data they receive on their own behalf. Id. 157. Section 502(c) provides: Except as otherwise provided in this subtitle, a nonaffiliated third party that receives from a financial institution nonpublic personal in- formation under this section shall not, directly or through an affiliate of such receiving third party, disclose such information to any other person that is a nonaffiliated third party of both the financial institu- tion and such receiving third party, unless such disclosure would be lawful if made directly to such other person by the financial institu- tion. GLB § 502(c), 113 Stat. at 1437. 158. See Office of the Press Secretary, White House, Clinton-Gore Plan to Enhance Consumers’ Financial Privacy: Protecting Core Values in the Infor- mation Age, (Apr. 30, 2000), available at www.privacy2000.org/archives (last visited Mar. 8, 2002) (“The plan also closes an unnecessary exception for ‘joint marketing’ from last year’s bill.”). 159. See H.R. 4380, 106th Cong (2000). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 140 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp purpose means that current law permits too wide a range of secondary uses. The problem of secondary uses is made worse by the sensitive nature of much of the data held by financial in- stitutions and shared under the joint marketing exception. In assessing the effects of eliminating the exception, it is important to note that marketing might still be conducted on behalf of the marketing partner. Unless there were some addi- tional legal provision that prohibited it, the original financial institution could send out marketing materials on behalf of the outside marketing partner. For instance, a bank could send out marketing materials on behalf of an outside firm, but the out- side firm would not receive any personal information from the bank. 160 The outside firm would not receive any personal data except after a choice by the customer. The choice would be ei- ther a GLB opt-out for transfers to third parties, or after the customer has decided to initiate a transaction with the market- ing partner. This approach allows marketing for a third party but not by a third party. It has the significant privacy advantage of preventing the data from flowing to a third party, with all of the attendant regulatory challenges of tracing how the data is used or disclosed once it has left the original financial institu- tion. It has the privacy disadvantage of permitting customers to be solicited by their own financial institutions on behalf of any outside party. To the extent one is concerned about this disadvantage, one can define the circumstances in which mar- keting for the third party is allowed. These sorts of definitions exist, for instance, in the medical privacy rule that the De- partment of Health and Human Services issued in final form in 2000. Under that rule, for instance, a marketing communica- tion must identify a hospital or other covered entity as the party making the communication, prominently disclose if the covered entity has received remuneration for making the com- munication, and offer an opt-out for future communications. 161 160. The data may be transferred to companies, such as companies special- izing in direct mailing, who actually send out the materials. These companies, however, would be agents of the original financial institution. They would be permitted to use the data only “on behalf of” the institution, and not for their own purposes. 161. “Marketing” is defined at Section 164.501 of the medical privacy rule. Section 164.514(e) sets forth these and other requirements that accompany marketing. For instance, if the covered entity targets a communication based on health status or condition, the communication must explain why the indi- vidual has been targeted and how the product or service relates to the health 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 141 Although some privacy advocates have criticized these market- ing provisions, 162 my own view is that this approach is sensible. An organization can contact its own customers, but if it con- ducts marketing on behalf of an outside firm, then the organi- zation has to identify itself and take responsibility for any ill- will generated by the unsolicited marketing effort. Offers that are genuinely in the interest of the customer will proceed, while offers seen by many customers as annoyances will trace back to the financial institution that conducts the marketing. Based on my work in the financial privacy area, including extensive discussions with stakeholders including industry and privacy groups, I would support eliminating the joint market- ing exception. I would also seriously explore drafting a market- ing provision analogous to that existing for medical privacy, so that marketing conducted for a third party could proceed only where the original financial institution clearly identified itself and took responsibility for making the marketing offer. As an alternative, Congress could retain the joint market- ing provision but strictly limit its use to its original justifica- tion. As discussed above, the provision was justified during the 1999 legislative debates as a mechanism for giving small finan- cial institutions parity with large institutions. The logical leg- islative response to this concern would be to design the joint marketing provision to apply specifically to small financial in- stitutions. For banks and other traditional financial institu- tions, there are numerous precedents for varying the regulatory regime depending on the size of the institution, such as the amount of assets held by a bank. 163 Congress might set size of the individual. Section 164.514(e)(3)(ii). 162. See, e.g., Robert O’Harrow, Jr., Patient Files Opened to Marketers, Fundraisers; Critics Decry Exemptions Won Through Lobbying, WASH. POST, Jan. 16, 2001, at E1 (quoting Robert Gellman and others criticizing the medi- cal privacy marketing provisions). 163. See, e.g., 12 C.F.R. Ch. III, Part 363.1 (2001) (annual independent au- dits and reporting requirements do not apply where an insured depository in- stitution’s total assets are less than $500 million); 12 C.F.R. Ch. I, Part 25, App. A(d) (2001) (small banks evaluated under different performance stan- dards for community reinvestment purposes). For a critique of many previous attempts to provide exemptions based on the small size of a business, see Richard J. Pierce, Jr., Small is Not Beautiful: The Case Against Special Regu- latory Treatment of Small Firms, 50 ADMIN. L. REV. 537 (1998). A joint mar- keting exception that applied only to small financial institutions might be more justifiable than the small-business exceptions criticized by Professor Pierce because the rationale for the exception is based precisely on the differ- ent way that small institutions conduct their business, rather than on alleged greater regulatory burdens suffered by small institutions. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 142 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp limits itself, or delegate the task to the relevant regulatory agencies. As a public policy matter, I am agnostic about the extent to which a small-institution exception is appropriate. 164 Small in- stitutions may indeed rely more heavily on joint marketing ar- rangements than large institutions which have affiliates, al- though I am not aware of any empirical support for this claim. In general, small databases likely pose fewer privacy risks than very large databases, so the privacy harm from a small- institution exception may be modest. 165 Whatever the need for a small-institution provision, concern about small institutions needing parity is simply no argument for the current wide-open exception used by the largest financial institutions. C. AFFILIATE SHARING A major disagreement in passage of GLB in 1999 and con- sideration of financial privacy legislation in 2000 was whether there should be an opt-out before data goes to affiliated institu- tions. 1. Defining the Scope of the Problem The number of affiliates in financial services is very high. Decades of regulation meant that there were multiple and compelling reasons for holding companies to create numerous subsidiaries. Geographic restrictions meant that banks typi- cally could not branch across state lines, and sometimes not even across county lines. 166 A holding company would own separate banks for separate geographic areas. Related lines of business, such as specialized lending subsidiaries, would be created in additional corporations when geographic limits did not apply to that line of business. 167 Service corporations, such 164. As a political matter, it is far easier for legislators to support a provi- sion that helps small banks compete effectively rather than a provision that is known to allow the largest conglomerates to share sensitive data freely. 165. For small databases, for instance, it is less likely to be cost effective to buy expensive data mining software for the smaller number of records. Those seeking information are also more likely to turn first to large databases that offer the possibility of comprehensive, one-stop information. 166. For an analysis of the law that historically applied to geographic ex- pansion of banking, see LISSA L. BROOME & JERRY W. MARKHAM, REGULATION OF BANK FINANCIAL SERVICE ACTIVITIES 591-625 (2001). 167. See the discussion of the development of interstate banking in JONATHAN R. MACEY, GEOFFREY P. MILLER & RICHARD S. CARNELL, BANKING LAW AND REGULATION 32-33 (3d ed. 2001). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 143 as those providing specialized computer services, would support many different affiliates. Special statutes meant that banking, insurance, and securities usually could not be done in the same corporation, even when pieces of the same holding company could offer the services. 168 Other regulatory and tax provisions gave additional reasons to house different activities in sepa- rate, affiliated corporations. 169 Many of the geographic and line-of-business restrictions eroded over time. Banks gained the full power to branch na- tionwide in 1994. 170 Securities activities were increasingly al- lowed in a bank holding company after regulatory changes in the late 1980s. 171 By the 1990s banks increasingly gained the power to offer insurance or insurance-like products, such as annuities. 172 By the time GLB was debated in 1999, it was roughly accurate to say that banking organizations could en- gage in all financial activities, but they had to undertake com- plex regulatory machinations to do so. For supporters of finan- cial modernization, this complexity raised the cost of entering new businesses, and meant that transactions were too often driven by regulatory peculiarities rather than the economic ef- ficiency. 173 For supporters of financial modernization, a great advan- tage of GLB was that it would spur a rationalization of the crazy-quilt structure of affiliates. The legacy of costly corporate separation would evolve into corporate structures that were based on market decisions about when to have separate affili- 168. For instance, bank holding companies were required to form affiliates outside of the bank when they gained new powers to underwrite securities. Sec. Indus. Ass’n. v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys., 807 F.2d 1052 (D.C. Cir. 1986), cert. denied, 483 U.S. 1005 (1987). 169. For instance, national banks were allowed to charge higher interest rates, notwithstanding the usury laws of a customer’s state, when loans were made from outside of that state. Marquette Nat’l Bank of Minneapolis v. First of Omaha Serv. Corp., 439 U.S. 299 (1978). 170. The prohibition on inter-state banking was repealed in the Riegle- Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994, Pub. L. No. 103-328, 108 Stat. 2338 (1994). 171. See Sec. Indus. Ass’n, 807 F.2d at 1058-59. 172. See Nationsbank of N. C., N.A. v. Variable Annuity Life Ins. Co., 513 U.S. 251, 257-58 (1995) (upholding national bank authority to offer annuities). 173. See generally Arthur E. Wilmarth Jr., The Transformation of the U.S. Financial Service Industry, 1975-2000: Competition, Consolidation, and In- creased Risks, U. ILL. L. REV. (forthcoming, 2002) (providing a detailed and disturbing critique of the effects of GLB on safety and soundness, with special attention to the risks created by combination of previously-separate lines of financial activity). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 144 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp ates. This rationalization would proceed gradually. In the early stages, new affiliates would start to coordinate their ac- tivities more closely. Over time, where the economic logic was strong, affiliates would merge together. Consumers, recogniz- ing this trend, would expect information sharing among affili- ates. 174 Given this history, one can construct a plausible case for at least a good deal of sharing of personal information among af- filiates. For affiliates that are on the road to a merger, sharing of data is a logical step toward eventual combined operations. More broadly, GLB offers the opportunity for banking, insur- ance, and securities activities to be marketed in a unified man- ner even where no merger is ultimately planned. For custom- ers who want “one-stop shopping” for their financial services, the post-GLB holding company can offer a comprehensive package. The seller can suggest just the product that the cus- tomer may need to construct a personal financial plan. Indeed, some industry leaders went so far as to say that the principal point of GLB was to facilitate this sort of cross-marketing. 175 174. Representative Oxley, a proponent of affiliate sharing, said that, “the integrated products and services today’s consumer expects from his or her fi- nancial institutions require information sharing, especially among affiliates. After all, in the eyes of the consumer, what are affiliates other than different departments of the same company that they are dealing with.” 145 CONG REC. H5310 (daily ed. July 1, 1999) (statement of Rep. Oxley). 175. For instance, Marcia Sullivan, a leading industry spokesperson on privacy issues, was reported as saying that “[o]verly strict privacy rules could even undermine the fundamental purpose of financial reform, which is to promote joint ventures, cross-marketing, and economic efficiencies.” Scott Barancik, House Privacy Hearing to Pit Banks Against White House, AM. BANKER, July 20, 1999, at 2. Jonathan Macey suggests a basis for affiliate sharing based on public choice theory rather than public policy: A more plausible explanation for the way that privacy issues are treated in the statute is that banks, insurance companies, and securi- ties firms doing business (or anticipating doing business) in financial services holding companies are far more politically powerful than the finance companies, regional financial intermediaries, and others ex- pected to remain independent after the statute was passed. Jonathan R. Macey, The Business of Banking: Before and After Gramm-Leach- Bliley, J. CORP. LAW, 691, 714 (2000). The interest groups that Professor Macey mentions certainly played an enormous role in shaping GLB. At the same time, a public choice approach would not have been very helpful in pre- dicting the precise outcome of privacy rules, which shifted repeatedly as the bill progressed through Congress, and with the Clinton Administration and privacy advocates as significant participants that Professor Macey does not mention. A public choice analysis, for instance, would find it difficult or im- possible to account for the sudden swing in the House Commerce Committee 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 145 This regulatory history helps one better appreciate the fer- vor of the debate in GLB over affiliate sharing of personal in- formation. From the industry side, a great deal of affiliate sharing was essential in order to rationalize operations and marketing in financial services. From the side of the privacy advocates, there were intense concerns about the agglomera- tion of previously separate databases from the banking, insur- ance, securities, and other industries. Ralph Nader, for in- stance, said: “The privacy protections that emerged in the banking reform legislation are a joke that will simply delude the public into believing privacy provisions exist where there are none.” 176 He focused his concern on sharing across data- bases: “[T]he affiliates of the conglomerates and their telemar- keters will be free to share many intimate details of an individ- ual's buying habits, investing patterns, health records, entertainment choices, employment data and other aspects of one's existence.” 177 The Clinton Administration also expressed serious con- cerns about allowing unfettered sharing of personal data with affiliates. In contrast to the privacy advocates, the Clinton Administration supported the general project of allowing bank- ing, securities, and the other lines of business to exist within a single holding company. 178 Together with the privacy advo- cates, however, the Administration believed that unfettered sharing of information with affiliates constituted a secondary use. During both the 1999 GLB debates and in its 2000 legisla- tive proposal, the Administration supported having an opt-out choice for sharing with affiliates. 179 to far greater privacy restrictions, including on affiliates, than favored by the industry groups that Professor Macey correctly describes as powerful. The approach taken in this article, rather than seeking to predict future develop- ments as a matter of public choice theory, is to assess what privacy rules would be desirable. 175. Ralph Nader, Banking Jackpot, WASH. POST, Nov. 5, 1999, at A33. 176. Id. 178. For instance, the White House press statement accompanying the signing of GLB began by saying: “President Clinton today will sign historic legislation to modernize our banking and finance laws. For the first time, fi- nancial firms will be able to offer a full range of banking, securities, and in- surance products, stimulating greater innovation and competition.” Press Re- lease, Office of the Press Secretary, The White House Financial Services Modernization for the 21st Century: Lowering Consumer Costs, Building Communities, and Boosting Competitiveness (Nov. 12, 1999), available at http://www.privacy2000.org/archives (last visited Mar. 8, 2002). 179. In signing GLB, President Clinton said: “Without restraining the eco- nomic potential of new business arrangements, I want to make sure every 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 146 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp The case for having an opt-out choice is strongest where the secondary use is very different from the primary use. In proposing stricter legislation in 2000, President Clinton gave examples: [T]he life insurance company could share information about your medical history with the bank without giving you any choice in the matter. The bank could share information from your student loans and your credit cards with its telemarketer, or its broker, again, with- out giving you any choice. I believe that is wrong. 180 As another example, consider whether a travel agency should be able to look through all the checks you wrote in the past year in order to assess what sort of vacations you might like. With the passage of GLB, these insurance companies, banks, telemarketers, brokers, travel agents, and others could easily be within the same financial holding company, under the broad terms of what is “incidental” or “complementary” to fi- nancial activities. 181 2. Responses to Affiliate Sharing The affiliate sharing issue is difficult because the argu- ments on both sides are so compelling. From the privacy side, the examples show the remarkable range of secondary uses permitted under GLB. The Clinton Administration believed that these secondary uses violated consumers’ reasonable ex- pectations, and consumer choice was therefore appropriate be- fore the information went to the different affiliate. From the industry side, a major achievement of GLB was to allow inte- grated operations for all types of financial services. Creating barriers to information sharing could severely undermine that achievement. As a discussed above, there are two basic ways that one could limit affiliate sharing. The formal approach would focus on corporate separateness, with use within a corporation per- mitted, but transfers to different corporations including affili- ates only done with consumer choice. This corporate separate- family has meaningful choices about how their personal information will be shared within corporate conglomerates. We can’t allow new opportunities to erode old and fundamental rights.” President Bill Clinton, Remarks by the President at Financial Modernization Bill Signing, (Nov. 12, 1999), available at http://www.privacy2000.org/archives (last visited Mar. 8, 2002). 180. President Bill Clinton, Remarks by the President at Eastern Michigan University Commencement, (Apr. 30, 2000), available at http:// www.privacy2000.org/archives (last visited Mar. 8, 2002). 181. 12 U.S.C. 1843(k) (2000). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 147 ness approach exists in GLB today, where transfers to unaffili- ated corporations require an opt-out but transfers within a holding company do not. Second, one the functional approach would permit data flows for some functions but require con- sumer choice for others. The functional approach also plays a role in GLB today, with the 502(e) exceptions permitting trans- fers to outside parties for purposes such as law enforcement, fraud prevention, and so forth. Transfers are also permitted, without consent, to those acting as agents for the financial in- stitution. As shown by GLB today, the formal and functional approaches can be used together, with transfers across corpo- rate boundaries usually requiring consumer choice but with designated exceptions where choice is not required. The Consumer Financial Privacy Act, proposed by the Clinton Administration in 2000, proposed what I believe is an attractive blend of the two approaches. Its basic rule is for- mal—sharing of data with affiliates requires a customer opt-out choice. This rule is supplemented with the existing functional exceptions to GLB, such as law enforcement, fraud prevention, and sharing with agents subject to a confidentiality contract. The rule is also supplemented by a new proposed provision for sharing with affiliates. This provision would allow sharing in order to facilitate customer service, such as maintenance and operation of consolidated customer call centers or the use of consolidated customer account statements. 182 The provision was developed after consultation with industry and consumer groups, and was based on a belief that consumers would gener- ally prefer a call center or other customer service operation to be able to provide information and carry out transactions for all of the customers’ transactions with the holding company. Oth- erwise, a customer with a checking account, mutual fund, and investment account might feel coerced to consent to unlimited information sharing within the holding company simply in or- der to gain the ability to have a single customer service repre- sentative who could see all three accounts. The CFPA also recognizes that stricter rules on informa- tion sharing are appropriate for especially sensitive categories of information. The bill proposes opt-in consent and other pro- tections against the inappropriate sharing of medical data within a holding company. 183 The bill also restricts the transfer 181. H.R. 4380, supra note ___, at § 10. 182. Id. at § 4. The bill prohibits offering a financial product or service based on health information unless there is affirmative consent by the cus- 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 148 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp of information about personal spending habits. For checking, credit card, and similar instruments, a financial institution would not be able to transfer to another company “an individu- alized list of that consumer’s transactions or an individualized description of that consumer’s interests, preferences, or other characteristics.” 184 To the extent that financial holding compa- nies contain personal information with varying levels of sensi- tivity, distinct rules can thus govern what data is shared with affiliates and outside companies. Instead of relying so much on formal corporate separate- ness, one can also imagine a more thoroughly functional ap- proach to governing sharing of data with affiliates. Even the strictest data privacy regimes recognize that data can be used for the purposes for which it was collected. When it comes to a checking account, for instance, a bank will use personal data in a variety of ways when completing transactions, auditing its own books, and sending customer statements. The tricky issue is how far to construe these primary purposes. In American practice, I suggest, consumers would generally expect that the data would be used in the same “line of business.” The monthly statement for a checking account, for instance, might include a solicitation for other banking products such as credit cards or certificate of deposit. If there is agreement that data can be shared within the same “line of business,” the next question is whether there are sensible extensions of that idea that correspond to consumer expectations and industry structure. For instance, my impres- sion is that many Americans would not be surprised or unduly disturbed if the fact that they were a customer of a bank was made available to the affiliated insurance, mutual fund, securi- ties broker, or other companies that might be called “core fi- nancial services.” Concerns about sharing financial informa- tion with these core financial services affiliates are relatively tomer after clear and conspicuous notice. To use medical data, the financial institution would also have to require the same information about all consum- ers as a condition of receiving the financial product or service. This last re- quirement was intended to reduce the risk that financial institutions would use health information in a discriminatory manner against only a few custom- ers; instead, an institution seeking health data would need to request the data of all of a product’s customers. Life insurance companies, for instance, might requires a physical examination of all applicants, but banks would be unlikely to risk the wrath of customers before asking for the medical data of mortgage applicants. 183. Id. at § 3. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 149 low. Indeed, many customers may prefer to receive a consoli- dated statement for banking, mutual fund, securities, and in- surance accounts. By contrast, concerns are greater when the sharing is done with affiliates that are not providing what I am calling “core financial services.” If Target, Marshall Fields, a travel agency, or other seemingly non-financial enterprises re- ceive the data, customers may understandably expect to have a choice before there is disclosure and secondary use. I believe there is a reasonably strong case to be made for considering this “core financial services” approach. The advan- tage is that opt-in or opt-out would not be required when shar- ing occurs among the core financial services. The integration of consumer banking, insurance, and securities products can con- tinue without the need to get a new opt-out for each transfer across corporate boundaries. As a correlate, an opt-out would be appropriate for transfers to affiliates that are not core finan- cial services. Transfer to the travel agency or retail store should be considered secondary use, subject to consumer choice. In suggesting this approach, I would like to address two potential objections. First is the question of administrability. How easy will it be to draw the line between core and periph- eral financial services? For the industry, the answer may be that it would be easier to draw such a line than to have to re- separate the banking, insurance, and securities activities. For regulators, there would indeed be a line-drawing challenge over time, although a large portion of actual consumer activities likely falls pretty clearly on one side of the line or the other. 185 Mutual funds are “core.” Travel agencies are not. The second, related objection is that the entire effort to pass Gramm-Leach-Bliley was precisely to get away from regu- latory line drawing among different types of financial institu- tions. Untold effort was spent, for instance, deciding whether a bank’s activities were impermissible “securities” or “insurance” activities. For weary veterans of these debates, it may seem bi- zarre to start a new regulatory effort based on distinguishing “core” from “peripheral” activities, with free information shar- ing only among the former. In response, I submit that the core/peripheral distinction avoids a key flaw of the pre-GLB regime. Under the old Glass- 184. Statutory support for this approach might come from GLB’s distinc- tions among “financial,” “incidental to financial,” and “complimentary to finan- cial” activities. See supra notes 36-37. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 150 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp Steagall approach, the regulatory categories meant the differ- ence between being able to enter a line of business or not. Companies were simply prohibited from doing certain activities if the wrong label—”securities” or “banking”—was applied. In- vestment in different sectors was distorted by these yes/no de- cisions on where activities could take place. By contrast, the core/periphery distinction would not determine whether a com- pany could engage in a particular activity. The distinction would have the lesser effect of merely requiring consumer choice before core financial information were shared for periph- eral purposes. Where companies believed it was worth enter- ing a line of business subject to this requirement, they could freely do so consistent with the free-investment philosophy of GLB. 186 To sum up on affiliate sharing, I believe that most consum- ers find unrestricted sharing among all affiliates to go consid- erably beyond their reasonable expectations. One way to ad- dress the issue is to follow the Consumer Financial Privacy Act, requiring choice before sharing with affiliates, creating appro- priate exceptions for customer service and other desirable flows, and providing stronger safeguards for the most sensitive information such as medical records and personal spending habits. Another way to address the issue is to explore a more functional approach, where sharing is allowed within each “line of business” and where greater choice is required when core fi- nancial services seek to share information with peripheral fi- nancial services. As financial institutions expand in scope, and the lines blur between financial activities and other activities in the economy, I believe it is not appropriate to assume that every item in a checking account or every balance in a mutual fund should be spread across the innumerable activities that a modern financial holding company is likely to operate. Looking ahead, I believe greater attention should be paid to identifying which data flows are most deserving of regulatory attention, which functional exceptions should be assured, along the lines for instance of the proposed customer service exception, and 186. A related justification for this approach is that it creates less of an in- centive to put a wide range of activities into the financial holding company. If the privacy regime favors affiliate sharing over sharing with third parties, then holding companies will have reason to expand the permissible scope of what can be brought within the holding company. On the other hand, if pe- ripheral financial activities are treated the same as third-party activities, this incentive will no longer exist. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 151 how to do all of this in a cost-effective way. 187 IV. NOTICES The notices to consumers required by GLB have been the target of vigorous attack from both industry and privacy advo- cates. Industry has complained that the notices impose a high cost for a low benefit. Estimates of the number of notices mailed out in 2001 range from one billion to 2.5 billion. 188 If each notice costs a first-class postage of 33 cents, as some in in- dustry have (perhaps erroneously) assumed, 189 then the annual costs could range from $300 million to over $800 million. 190 What is gained from all of this paper? The actual number of opt-outs appears to be low, with five percent the most widely used figure but with some estimates of under one percent. 191 187. Concerning cost-effectiveness, my judgment is that a greater time should be allowed for implementation once legislation is enacted. The most effective and least expensive way to change data handling practices is when a system is updated. Instead of the six months given for implementation with the GLB rule, I would favor something on the order of a two year implementa- tion schedule. In this way, industry could comply more cost-effectively, and otherwise-justified complaints about an unrealistic time schedule would have considerably less force in the political process. 188. W.A. Lee, Opt-Out Notices Give No One a Thrill, AM. BANKER, July 10, 2001, at 1 (more than a billion notices). 189. Many banks included the privacy notice in customer statements or other mailings, reducing printing and postage costs. 190. Ted Cornwell, Privacy Regulations Require System Upgrades, MORTGAGE SERVICING NEWS, Oct. 2000, at 1. Citing an attorney who repre- sents banking industry clients, the article states that the financial services industry will send at least 2.5 billion pieces of mail, with postage of 33 cents each, for a total cost of $825 million. Another potential cost would be due to the change in the information sys- tems of financial institutions, which now will have to be able to keep track of consumer opt-outs in order to share personal information only where permit- ted. It is an interesting question how much to count these system changes as a cost of the regulation. If one assumes, as a baseline, that all personal infor- mation can be freely shared with all outside parties, then it is a cost of the regulation to place any limits on information sharing. If one assumes, by con- trast, that personal information should be sent to outside parties only with the choice of the individual, then the system costs are part of the normal cost of doing business rather than a new cost of the regulation. This question of how to define the baseline is extensively discussed in the cost/benefit analysis for the HIPAA medical privacy regulation. 65 Fed. Reg. 82762 (2000). 191. Marie Harf, Nader Slams GLB Privacy Compliance, AM. BANKER, June 22, 2001, at 1 (consumer advocate Ralph Nader discusses five percent reply rate); Lee, supra note 188 (five percent “has been circulating as the unof- ficial industry figure”). A survey by an industry group, America’s Community Bankers, reported that about half the thrifts with over $ 1 billion in assets offered the opt-out. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 152 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp From an industry perspective, therefore, the notices can seem like an expensive exercise on an issue that consumers indicate they care little about. Consumer groups, privacy advocates, and Members of Congress have also harshly criticized the GLB notices. In the summer of 2001, a coalition of groups petitioned the regulators to issue new notice rules, alleging that “most financial institu- tions have employed dense, misleading statements and confus- ing, cumbersome procedures to prevent consumers from opting out.” 192 Representative John LaFalce, the ranking Democrat on the House Banking Committee, wrote a detailed letter to regu- lators stating that many of the notices fail to meet the “clear and conspicuous” notice requirement of the statute: “While a number of financial institutions have worked constructively to create effective privacy notices and opt out vehicles, too many others appear to have used the privacy notices to confuse their privacy obligations and engage in inappropriate marketing.” 193 Representative LaFalce said the notices “are not readily notice- able among the marketing and promotional materials that con- sumers frequently ignore in monthly statements.” 194 Notices are too long, the language is too complex, and the tone “mini- mizes the importance of the consumer’s opt-out right.” 195 A. THE CASE FOR THE CURRENT, FLAWED NOTICES To a certain extent, the industry and advocate comments about the notices show a predictable taking of positions rather (Institutions that do not transfer customer information to non-affiliated third parties do not need to offer the opt-out.) Of these thrifts, 60 percent said that less than one percent of their customers elected to opt out. Rob Blackwell, Privacy Costs Hitting Small Players Harder, AM. BANKER, Nov. 21, 2001, at 1. The representativeness of this survey is subject to doubt, however. The re- sponse rate to the survey was low, the sample size for the less than one per- cent finding was small, and it is unknown how clear the notices were or how easy it was for consumers to opt out. 192. Petition for Rulemaking, July 26, 2001, at 2, available at http://epic.org/privacy/consumer/glbpetition.pdf (last visited Mar. 13, 2002). 193. Letter from Representative John J. LaFalce et al. to Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, et al., (June 22, 2001), available at http://www.house.gov/banking-democrats/pr_0106letter .htm (last visited Mar. 13, 2002). 194. Id. 195. Id. Rep. LaFalce discussed a study by the Privacy Rights Clearing- house that found that the average privacy notice “was written at a third or fourth year college level, well above the junior high school reading level typi- cally considered ‘widely understandable’ for purposes of government notices and business marketing.” Id. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 153 than commentary on actual flaws of the current approach. For instance, industry would likely try to have it both ways when it becomes to discussing the implications of the opt-out rate. With the low current opt-out rate, industry argues that con- sumers are showing they don’t care much about privacy, so there should be minimal privacy regulation. If the opt-out rate had been high, however, then industry would have argued that privacy protections interfered too much with their ability to carry out their business, so that again there should be minimal privacy regulation. This position-taking can occur as well from the privacy advocate side. With the low current opt-out rate, the point is that the notices are badly flawed, so stricter privacy protections are needed. If the opt-out rate had been high, this would have been evidence of how much consumers care about privacy, supporting stricter privacy protections. In short, the evidence on rate of opt out does not do much to sway the views of either side of the debate. Recognizing the criticisms to date, and the limits of the available evidence, I would like to make the case for a decidedly more optimistic view of the effect of the GLB notices. Even in their current flawed form and even if not a single consumer ex- ercised the opt-out right, I contend that a principal effect of the notices has been to require financial institutions to inspect their own practices. In this respect, the detail and complexity of the GLB notices is actually a virtue. In order to draft the no- tice, many financial institutions undertook an extensive proc- ess, often for the first time, to learn just how data is and is not shared between different parts of the organization and with third parties. Based on my extensive discussions with people in the industry, I believe that many institutions discovered practices that they decided, upon deliberation, to change. One public example of this was the decision of Bank of America no longer to share its customers’ data with third parties, even sub- ject to opt-out. 196 The detailed and complex notice, in short, created a more detailed roadmap for privacy compliance. Related to this process of self-examination, many financial companies put in place new institutional structures for manag- ing privacy and security. The most visible symptom of these changes has been the spread of the “Chief Privacy Officer.” The number of CPOs rose rapidly in the immediate aftermath of 196. Michelle Heller, Cost of Compliance Could Deter Data-Sharing, AM. BANKER, June 26, 2000, at 1. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 154 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp GLB. 197 Based on my own experience as essentially the CPO for the Federal government, 198 I believe having a person visibly responsible for privacy is a helpful way to ensure that privacy issues are considered in the organization’s actions. Privacy concerns may or may not win out in the eventual decisions, but having a person expert in privacy in the process means that the other participants at least have to articulate why the proposed actions are consistent with the organization’s announced pri- vacy policies. Even for those financial institutions that chose not to name a CPO, there were often people in the general counsel’s office or elsewhere in the organization who gained new responsibilities for creating and implementing privacy policies. The institutionalization of privacy, in short, is per- haps the single most important and least appreciated effect of GLB. The privacy notice to all consumers, coupled with liabil- ity for violation of the notice, prompted a larger compliance ef- fort than most observers have realized. One important and related benefit, I believe, is that GLB substantially reduces the risk of egregious privacy practices by financial institutions. A comparison to environmental regula- tion illustrates the point. Suppose a new legal regime greatly reduced the likelihood of large toxic waste spills, measured in pounds or tons, but left in place the likelihood of low-level re- leases, measured in fractions of a pound. Critics of the law might justifiably complain that low-level releases continued. Supporters of the law, however, could say with some confidence 197. The Privacy Officers Association was started in early 2000. Mark Taylor, Privacy Issues are Focus of New Group, MODERN HEALTHCARE, April 10, 2000, at 42. For general reports of the rise of CPOs, see Michelle Kessler, Position of ‘Privacy Officer’ Coming into Public Eye, U.S.A. TODAY, Nov. 30, 2000, at 1B (noting that in the past 2 years the number of companies with CPOs rose from zero to seventy-five), Mary Mosquera, , IT Companies Go Pub- lic About Privacy, TECHWEB, Dec. 19, 2000, at http://content.techweb.com/ wire/story/TWB20001219S0016 (last visited Mar. 16, 2002) (noting companies such as Microsoft, IBM, and AT&T had all recently created the CPO position). 198. My title was “Chief Counselor for Privacy” in the U.S. Office of Man- agement and Budget. At the time we named the new position in early 1999, I had never heard of the term “Chief Privacy Officer,” and we did not use that title. Ray Everett-Church began using the “Chief Privacy Officer” title in Sept. 1999.AllAdvantage.com scores $31m + strategic allies with next-level Internet plan, M2 PRESS WIRE, Sept. 10, 1999. He was the Internet’s first CPO. Id. Harriet Pearson was named CPO of IBM on November 29, 2000. IBM Names Exec to Direct Internet Privacy Concerns, L.A. TIMES, Nov. 30, 2000, at C6, In- ternational Business Machines Corp.: Computer Maker’s Pearson Named First Privacy Chief, WALL ST. J. Nov. 30, 2000, at B13 (same). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 155 that the level of pollution would decline considerably, with a consequent gain for the public health. 199 Supporters would also say that institutional learning from the first round of legisla- tion might teach valuable lessons for cost-effective efforts in the future to restrict the low-level releases. I suggest that the environmental analogy is apt. The U.S. Bank case was the equivalent of a large spill, with the detailed records of hundreds of thousands of customers going to a tele- marketing company that engaged in apparently deceptive prac- tices, all without any notice to customers. In the wake of GLB, with privacy practices enforceable by law and the new CPO on the scene, is this sort of large spill nearly as likely to occur? The notice alerts employees and customers alike that privacy is part of the responsibility of the financial institution. Disgrun- tled employees, emboldened perhaps in the post-Enron period, will be able to cause considerable problems if they blow the whistle on unlawful or inappropriate privacy practices. The in- stitution’s managers will be educated to avoid the risks of prac- tices that, in the words of Comptroller Jerry Hawke, will ap- pear “seamy” to the regulators, the press, and the public. Bank supervisors will examine for compliance with privacy and secu- rity policies. As discussed above in connection with the joint marketing exception and affiliate sharing, I believe GLB allows too many spills of data without customer choice. Nonetheless, these spills occur within a framework that makes large, un- regulated transfers to third parties much less likely. Egregious practices become risky for the company, even though less egre- gious practices continue in violation of what fair information practices would generally contemplate. B. CREATING BETTER NOTICES The analysis here suggests a dilemma in drafting GLB pri- vacy policies. Neither a long nor a short notice seems accept- able. The virtues of long and detailed notices are that they have pushed companies to inventory and document their privacy practices, create institutional compliance structures, and avoid 199. Indeed, there is a considerable literature in the environmental area that suggests that the ratio of benefits to costs is greatest for the first genera- tion of regulation. Mandatory rules often are most justified for behavior that clearly should be prohibited. The likelihood of net benefits declines as prohibi- tions apply to behavior that is not per se objectionable. See, e.g., Robert V. Percival, et al., Environmental Regulation 151 (3d ed.) (showing general as- sumption that net benefits are greatest for the early stages of regulation). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 156 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp egregious practices. The vices of such notices are that ordinary consumers don’t understand them—the right to opt out is swathed in folds of obscuring verbiage. On the other hand, a short and plain English notice would have the virtue of com- municating more clearly to most consumers. This summary document, however, would be far less effective at prompting self-scrutiny of company practices and would be in such general terms that holding violators accountable would be essentially impossible. The sensible way out of this dilemma is to have both a short and a long notice, with each used in appropriate circum- stances. 200 For communications with consumers, the general approach would be to provide a short, plain English notice. The policy goal here should be to design notices that communicate effectively about privacy choices. Focus groups and other con- sumer survey techniques can aid in this task. To facilitate comparison shopping, it quite possibly makes sense to have a standardized format, as with nutrition labels. 201 Institutions should also continue to have a more detailed notice, which sets forth the longer list of facts that are material to understanding and implementing a company’s actual privacy policies. The short notice would tell how to access the detailed notice, presumably including a web link , and perhaps with the notice included in Securites and Exchange Commission docu- ments. 202 The detailed notice might roughly correspond to the 200. As this article was being written, the federal regulators held a work- shop in December, 2001 to study GLB notices. Interagency Public Workshop, Get Noticed: Effective Financial Privacy Notices, (Dec. 4, 2001), available at http://www.ftc.gov/bcp/workshops/glb/index.html (including transcripts and presentations). Several of the participants at the workshop discussed the pos- sibility of a two-tiered notice along the general lines proposed here. 201. I do not have a firm view on the extent to which the format should be standardized by regulation. One can construct plausible arguments for having one standard form, or a group of standard forms for major industries, or a safe harbor for companies that use a standard form with the option for companies to design variations. However much standardization occurs by legal action, the goals would be to communicate clearly, signal the choices that consumers have, and facilitate comparison shopping. 202. Having a link to a web page has important advantages including : (1) updates of the policy can be done on a single web page, at considerably lower cost than printing policies; (2) consumers can review the detailed policy before they begin doing business with an institution; and (3) compliance is easier, both for employees and those on the outside, when there is an authoritative place to go to read the current policy. IDFN Taking this approach a step further, regulators should consider having a registry for the privacy policies of the financial institutions they regulate. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 157 length of the current notice, although policymakers and finan- cial institutions may wish to add or subtract detail over time. The policy goal here is to have a privacy policy that is detailed enough to ensure self-scrutiny, provide a mechanism for insti- tutions to continue with internal compliance functions, and al- low enforcement in the presumably rare cases where an insti- tution is violating its stated policies. This two-tier approach adds considerable flexibility to the notice regime. There can be cost savings for institutions where it makes sense to provide only the shorter notice. For instance, a bank branch could have an easy-to-read flier in its lobby rather than providing six or eight pages of dense typeface. 203 It may be appropriate to save costs and include only the short no- tice in the annual mailing to customers, with a prominent link to the detailed notice. Updating of the detailed notice can also be done at lower cost, without the need to print and distribute notices to all customers for minor changes. The two-tier approach also builds on the experience of other regulatory systems. Under the Privacy Act, for instance, federal agencies give a short notice on forms that collect per- sonal information from the public. The details of how informa- tion is shared, including the so-called “routine uses,” are then published in the Federal Register. 204 As with the proposed two- tier notices for GLB, agencies are held accountable to the de- tailed statements in the routine uses, with the short forms primarily designed to communicate clearly with the public. Another useful comparison is to the securities disclosure laws established in the 1930s. The securities regime emerged to correct for the perceived lack of accurate disclosure in the All banks regulated by the Comptroller of the Currency, for instance, might be expected to place their current policies on the Comptroller’s web site, search- able by bank name. Consumers could then comparison shop, journalists and watchdog groups could easily review privacy policies, and a dated log could ex- ist of what an institution’s policy was at any given time. The burden on indus- try would be the minimal cost of posting an already-drafted privacy policy to the Comptroller’s page. A registry with some of these features exists currently for companies that have signed up with the U.S. Department of Commerce’s “Safe Harbor” program for transfers of personal data from the European Un- ion to the United States. U.S. DEP’T OF COMMERCE, SAFE HARBOR (2002), at http://www.export.gov/safeharbor/ (last visited Mar. 13, 2002) (describing safe harbor); see also http://web.ita.doc.gov/safeharbor/shlist.nsf/webPages/ safe+harbor+list (listing entities participating in the safe harbor). 203. The notice in the lobby might clearly note that a more detailed notice is available upon request. 204. 5 U.S.C. 552a(e)(4) (2000). 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 158 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp stock market during the 1920s. Similarly, the privacy regime can be seen as a way to correct for the lack of accurate disclo- sure by U.S. Bank and, by implication, other financial organi- zations. In looking at securities disclosures, few observers be- lieve that the prospectuses released by public companies are in plain English or are designed primarily in order to communi- cate effectively with the ordinary investor. 205 The detailed no- tices, however, require disclosure of all material facts and have resulted in an extensive internal process in most companies to determine the material facts and decide what to disclose. The detailed notices also facilitate enforcement if a company fails to disclose or is misleading in its disclosure. Another advantage of the two-tier approach is how it re- solves frustrations in the current debate. Currently, any re- quest for more detail in the notice is greeted with the observa- tion that the disclosures are already too long and confusing for most consumers. Any request for plain English is greeted with the companies’ concern that broad promises will lead to viola- tions and enforcement actions. Simple and short statements also concern privacy advocates who fear that companies will be afraid to make broad privacy promises and so will reserve the right to do whatever they wish with personal information. The two-tier approach, by contrast, allows plainer English in the short form and greater detail in the long form, while quite pos- sibly reducing overall costs due to reduced printing costs where the short form is appropriate. CONCLUSION This article has examined the surprising merits of the new financial privacy law. From the privacy side, Title V of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act has moved financial institutions a long step toward implementation of the fair information prac- tices of notice, choice, access, security, and enforcement. Due to the broad definition of “financial institution,” the law brings these basic privacy principles to a wide range of organizations. Due to the ability of the states to enact stricter privacy protec- 205. Regulators periodically try to make the disclosures more reader friendly, with limited success. See 17 C.F.R. § 228-30, 239, 274 (1998), SEC Plain English Disclosures, available at http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/33- 7497.txt. The analysis here suggests that achieving readability for security prospectuses is not the over-arching goal. Another goal, more important in many respects, is to create a document that provides detailed disclosures against which the company can be held accountable. 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 2002] MERITS OF FINANCIAL PRIVACY LAW 159 tions, there is a credible threat of new financial privacy legisla- tion, and financial institutions thus have an ongoing incentive to convince legislators and the public that they are acting re- sponsibly with individuals’ data. This credible threat of further privacy legislation creates the possibility of re-examining the most important weakness in the current GLB law, which is the limited nature of choice be- fore individuals’ data is shared with other institutions. For the issue of choice, this article has advocated the elimination of the “joint marketing exception,” which was justified in Congress as a way to help small banks but has been used instead as a major loophole for large financial institutions. This article has also advocated exploring any of several approaches to the issue of sharing with affiliates in the sprawling financial holding com- panies that GLB creates. One approach is that included in the Clinton Administration’s proposed Consumer Financial Privacy Act, which would have required an opt-out choice for affiliate sharing. Another approach would adopt a general “line of business” rule, with sharing freely permitted within the same line of business but choice required before data is sent to differ- ent lines of business. This approach is essentially what applies under current European data protection rules. A related ap- proach would define a set of “core” consumer financial services, with sharing permitted within this core but choice required be- fore data is sent to “peripheral” financial institutions such as travel agencies or affiliated retailers. Within any of these ap- proaches, it would be important to allow sharing for pro- consumer purposes such as fraud reduction and customer ser- vice, while seeking ways to prevent sharing in violation of rea- sonable consumer expectations. From the business side, the experience to date with GLB indicates that protection of consumer privacy is consistent with financial modernization. GLB has allowed the merger or joint operation of consumer financial services companies that the old regulatory regime had kept separate. It makes sense to con- tinue the trend toward having market forces rather than regu- lators determine which financial services should be offered jointly to consumers. At the same time, the case for merging financial services with non-financial businesses is far less clear. Keeping sensitive financial data within financial firms, while limiting its release to non-financial firms, is largely consistent both with good business practice and good privacy practice. This article has also explained the surprising virtues of the 347402.DOC 11/25/2002 11:27 PM 160 MINNESOTA LAW REVIEW [Vol.86:pppp GLB notice requirements. I agree with the critics that many of the current notices are very detailed and practically unread- able. This level of detail, however, brings with it important ad- vantages. Notably, financial institutions have had to engage in considerable self-scrutiny of their data handling practices. This scrutiny has resulted in many institutions discovering practices that they decided to change. Many companies have also insti- tutionalized privacy protection for the first time, by naming chief privacy officers or in other ways. By requiring financial institutions to make privacy promises, and making those prom- ises enforceable for the first time, GLB has been an important step toward eliminating the most egregious practices and creat- ing a structure for continued improvement over time. The path to better notices, moreover, is quite clear. De- tailed notices should be retained because they create the possi- bility of detailed accountability. At the same time, much shorter and more readable notices are appropriate in many in- stances. These short-form notices can resemble nutrition labels in highlighting the most important privacy information. They should be designed with attention to how to communicate effec- tively with consumers, while providing a ready link to the longer notices for those who want the details. With this two- tier approach, the notices can promote both accountability and clear communication, and likely save costs to the industry by permitting shorter, less-expensive notices to be distributed in many settings. This article’s focus on choice and notice is not intended to ignore other important debates and issues in the financial pri- vacy area. Current law has a loophole that would allow medi- cal information to be shared too freely within a financial hold- ing company. Much more can be said about how to choose between an opt-in and opt-out choice. Stronger protections are likely appropriate for the personal spending habits revealed by consumers’ checking or credit card accounts. These and other issues were included in the Clinton Administration’s Consumer Privacy Protection Act, which I continue to support. It would be surprising indeed if a sprawling law such as Gramm-Leach- Bliley got everything right. Perhaps more surprisingly, how- ever, the law provides a better basis for good privacy and good business practice than one would suspect.