Yale Law School
Program for Studies in Law,
Economics, and Public Policy
Law and Economics Working Paper No. 235
New York University
Center for Law and Business
Law and Economics Working Paper No. 013
Harvard Law School
John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics, and Business
Discussion Paper No. 280
Yale
International Center for Finance
Working Paper No. 00-09
The End of History for Corporate Law
January 2000
Henry Hansmann and Reinier Kraakman
This paper can be downloaded without charge from:
The Harvard John M. Olin Discussion Paper Series:
http://www.law.harvard.edu/programs/olin_center/
The Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=204528
THE END OF HISTORY FOR CORPORATE LAW
Henry Hansmann
Yale Law School
Visiting, NYU School of Law
Reinier Kraakman
Harvard Law School
January 2000
Comments welcome. Send correspondence to:
Henry Hansmann
NYU School of Law, Room 335
40 Washington Square South
New York, NY 10012
212-998-6132
212-995-4763 fax
henry.hansmann@yale.edu
Reinier Kraakman
Harvard Law School
Cambridge, MA 02138
617-496-3586
617-496-6118 fax
kraakman@law.harvard.edu
Earlier drafts of this essay were presented at conferences entitled “Are Corporate
Governance Systems Converging?” held at Columbia Law School, December 5,
1997, and “Convergence and Diversity in Corporate Governance Regimes and
Capital Markets,” sponsored by Tilburg University in Eindhoven, The Netherlands,
on November 4 - 5, 1999. We both wish to thank the New York University School of
Law and its Dean, John Sexton, for generous support in this project while both
authors were visiting professors.
The End of History for Corporate Law
by
Henry Hansmann
Yale Law School
Reinier Kraakman
Harvard Law School
ABSTRACT
Despite the apparent divergence in institutions of governance, share ownership,
capital markets, and business culture across developed economies, the basic law of the
corporate form has already achieved a high degree of uniformity, and continued
convergence is likely. A principal reason for convergence is a widespread normative
consensus that corporate managers should act exclusively in the economic interests of
shareholders, including noncontrolling shareholders. This consensus on a shareholder-
oriented model of the corporation results in part from the failure of alternative models of the
corporation, including the manager-oriented model that evolved in the U.S. in the 1950's
and 60's, the labor-oriented model that reached its apogee in German co-determination,
and the state-oriented model that until recently was dominant in France and much of Asia.
Other reasons for the new consensus include the competitive success of contemporary
British and American firms, the growing influence worldwide of the academic disciplines of
economics and finance, the diffusion of share ownership in developed countries, and the
emergence of active shareholder representatives and interest groups in major
jurisdictions. Since the dominant corporate ideology of shareholder primacy is unlikely to
be undone, its success represents the “end of history” for corporate law.
The ideology of shareholder primacy is likely to press all major jurisdictions toward
similar rules of corporate law and practice. Although some differences may persist as a
result of institutional or historical contingencies, the bulk of legal development worldwide
will be toward a standard legal model of the corporation. For the most part, this
development will enhance the efficiency of corporate laws and practices. In some cases,
however, jurisdictions may converge on inefficient rules, as when the universal rule of
limited shareholder liability permits shareholders to externalize the costs of corporate torts.
JEL Classifications: F20, G34, K22
1. See, e.g., Mark Roe, Some Differences in Company Structure in Germany,
Japan, and the United States, 102 YALE L. J. 1927 (1993); Ronald J. Gilson & Mark J.
Roe, Understanding the Japanese Keiretsu: Overlaps Between Company Governance
and Industrial Organization, 102 YALE L. J. 871 (1993); Bernard S. Black & John C.
Coffee, Hail Britannia? Institutional Investor Behavior Under Limited Regulation, 92
MICH. L. REV. 1997 (1994).
2. See Henry Hansmann and Reinier Kraakman, The Essential Role of
Organizational Law (Yale Law School and Harvard Law School, 1999).
1
I. INTRODUCTION
Recent scholarship has emphasized institutional differences in governance, share
ownership, capital markets, and business culture among European, American, and
Japanese companies.1 Despite this apparent divergence, however, the basic law of
corporate governance -- indeed, most of corporate law -- has achieved a high degree of
uniformity across these jurisdictions, and continuing convergence toward a single standard
model is likely. The core legal features of the corporate form were already well
established in advanced jurisdictions 100 years ago, at the turn of the twentieth century.
Although there remained considerable room for variation in governance practices and in
the fine structure of corporate law throughout the twentieth century, the pressures for further
convergence are now rapidly growing. Chief among these pressures is the recent
dominance of a shareholder-centered ideology of corporate law among the business,
government, and legal elites in key commercial jurisdictions. There is no longer any
serious competitor to the view that corporate law should principally strive to increase long-
term shareholder value. This emergent consensus has already profoundly affected
corporate governance practices throughout the world. It is only a matter of time before its
influence is felt in the reform of corporate law as well.
II. CONVERGENCE PAST: THE RISE OF THE CORPORATE FORM
We must begin with the recognition that the law of business corporations had
already achieved a remarkable degree of worldwide convergence at the end of the
nineteenth century. By that time, large-scale business enterprise in every major
commercial jurisdiction had come to be organized in the corporate form, and the core
functional features of that form were essentially identical across these jurisdictions. Those
features, which continue to characterize the corporate form today, are: (1) full legal
personality, including well-defined authority to bind the firm to contracts and to bond those
contracts with assets that are the property of the firm as distinct from the firm’s owners,2 (2)
limited liability for owners and managers, (3) shared ownership by investors of capital, (4)
delegated management under a board structure, and (5) transferable shares.
3. Henry Hansmann and Reinier Kraakman, What is Corporate Law? , Chapter 1 in
Reinier Kraakman, Gerard Hertig, Henry Hansmann, & Hideki Kanda, eds, THE ANATOMY
OF CORPORATE LAW: A COMPARATIVE AND FUNCTIONAL APPROACH (working draft, June
1999); Henry Hansmann, The OWNERSHIP OF ENTERPRISE (1996).
4. Phillip Blumberg, THE LAW OF CORPORATE GROUPS: SUBSTANTIVE LAW, 9-20
(1988).
2
These core characteristics, both individually and in combination, offer important
efficiencies in organizing the large firms with multiple owners that have come to dominate
developed market economies. We explore those efficiencies in detail elsewhere.3 What
is important to note here is that, while those characteristics and their associated
efficiencies are now commonly taken for granted, prior to the beginning of the nineteenth
century there existed only a handful of specially chartered companies that combined all five
of these characteristics. The joint stock company with tradeable shares was not made
generally available for business activities in England until 1844, and limited liability was not
added to the form until 1855.4 While some American states developed the form for
general use a few years earlier, all general business corporation statues appear to date
from well after 1800. By around 1900, however, every major commercial jurisdiction
appears to have provided for at least one standard-form legal entity with the five
characteristics listed above as the default rules, and this has remained the case ever
since.
Thus there was already strong and rapid convergence a century ago regarding the
basic elements of the law of business corporations. It is, in general, only in the more
detailed structure of corporate law that jurisdictions have varied significantly since then.
The five basic characteristics of the corporate form provide, by their nature, for a
firm that is strongly responsive to shareholder interests. They do not, however, necessarily
dictate how the interests of other participants in the firm -- such as employees, creditors,
other suppliers, customers, or society at large -- will be accommodated. Nor do they
dictate the way in which conflicts of interest among shareholders themselves – and
particularly between controlling and noncontrolling shareholders – will be resolved.
Throughout most of the twentieth century there has been debate over these issues, and
experimentation with alternative approaches to them.
Recent years, however, have brought strong evidence of a growing consensus on
these issues among the academic, business, and governmental elites in leading
jurisdictions. The principal elements of this consensus are that ultimate control over the
corporation should be in the hands of the shareholder class; that the managers of the
corporation should be charged with the obligation to manage the corporation in the
interests of its shareholders; that other corporate constituencies, such as creditors,
3
employees, suppliers, and customers should have their interests protected by contractual
and regulatory means rather than through participation in corporate governance; that
noncontrolling shareholders should receive strong protection from exploitation at the hands
of controlling shareholders; and that the principal measure of the interests of the publicly
traded corporation’s shareholders is the market value of their shares in the firm. For
simplicity, we shall refer to the view of the corporation that comprises these elements as
the “standard shareholder-oriented model” of the corporate form (or, for brevity, simply “the
standard model”). To the extent that corporate law bears on the implementation of this
standard model – as to an important degree it does – this consensus on the appropriate
conduct of corporate affairs is also a consensus as to the appropriate content of corporate
law, and is likely to have profound effects on the structure of that law.
Thus, just as there was rapid crystallization of the core features of the corporate
form in the late nineteenth century, at the beginning of the twenty-first century we are
witnessing rapid convergence on the standard shareholder-oriented model as a normative
view of corporate structure and governance, and we should expect this normative
convergence to produce substantial convergence as well in the practices of corporate
governance and in corporate law.
There are three principal factors driving consensus on the standard model: the
failure of alternative models; the competitive pressures of global commerce; and the shift
of interest group influence in favor of an emerging shareholder class. We consider these
developments here in sequence.
III. THE FAILURE OF ALTERNATIVE MODELS
Debate and experimentation concerning the basic structure of corporate law during
the twentieth century centered on the ways in which that law should accommodate the
interests of non-shareholder constituencies. In this regard, three principal alternatives to a
shareholder-oriented model were the traditional foci of attention. We term these the
manager-oriented, the labor-oriented, and the state-oriented models of corporate law.
Although each of these three alternative models has -- at various points and in various
jurisdictions -- achieved some success both in practice and in received opinion, all three
have ultimately lost much of their normative appeal.
Recent academic literature has focused on the “stakeholder” model of the
corporation as the principal alternative to the shareholder-oriented model. The
stakeholder model, however, is essentially just a combination of elements found in the
older manager-oriented and labor-oriented models. Consequently, the same forces that
have been discrediting the latter models are also undermining the stakeholder model as a
viable alternative to the shareholder-oriented model.
5. Dodd and Berle conducted a classic debate on the subject in the 1930's, in which
Dodd pressed the social responsibility of corporate managers while Berle championed
shareholder interests. Adolph A. Berle, Corporate Powers as Powers in Trust, 44
HARVARD LAW REVIEW 1049 (1931); E. Merrick Dodd, For Whom are Corporate
Managers Trustees? 45 HARVARD LAW REVIEW 1145 (1932); Adolph Berle, For Whom
Corporate Managers Are Trustees: A Note, 45 HARVARD LAW REVIEW 1365 (1932). By
the 1950's, Berle seemed to have come around to Dodd’s celebration of managerial
discretion as a positive virtue that permits managers to act in the interests of society as a
whole. See Adolph A. Berle, POWER WITHOUT PROPERTY: A NEW DEVELOPMENT IN
AMERICAN POLITICAL ECONOMY 107-110 (1959). John Kenneth Galbraith takes a similar
position in THE NEW INDUSTRIAL STATE (1967).
6. See, e.g., Galbraith, supra, and Berle (1959), supra. For an important collection of
essays arguing both sides of the question of managerial responsibility to the broader
interests of society, see Edward Mason, ed., THE CORPORATION IN MODERN SOCIETY
(1959).
4
A. The Manager-Oriented Model
In the U.S., there existed an important strain of normative thought from the 1930s
through the 1960s that extolled the virtues of granting substantial discretion to the
managers of large business corporations. Merrick Dodd and John Kenneth Galbraith, for
example, were conspicuously identified with this position, and Adolph Berle came to it late
in life.5 At the core of this view was the belief that professional corporate managers could
serve as disinterested technocratic fiduciaries who would guide business corporations to
perform in ways that would serve the general public interest. The corporate social
responsibility literature of the 1950s can be seen as an embodiment of these views.6
The normative appeal of this view arguably provided part of the rationale for the
various legal developments in U.S. law in the 1950s and 1960s that tended to reinforce the
discretionary authority of corporate managers, such as the SEC proxy rules and the
Williams Act. The collapse of the conglomerate movement in the 1970s and 1980s,
however, largely destroyed the normative appeal of the managerialist model. It is now the
conventional wisdom that, when managers are given great discretion over corporate
investment policies, they mostly end up serving themselves, however well-intentioned they
may be. While managerial firms may be in some ways more efficiently responsive to
nonshareholder interests than are firms that are more dedicated to serving their
shareholders, the price paid in inefficiency of operations and excessive investment in low-
value projects is now considered too dear.
7. Proposal for a Fifth Company Law Directive, 1983 O.J. (C240)2.
5
B. The Labor-Oriented Model
Large-scale enterprise clearly presents problems of labor contracting. Simple
contracts, and the basic doctrines of contract law, are inadequate in themselves to govern
the long-term relationships between workers and the firms that employ them –
relationships that may be afflicted by, among other things, substantial transaction-specific
investments and asymmetries of information.
Collective bargaining via organized unions has been one approach to those
problems -- an approach that lies outside corporate law, since it is not dependent on the
organizational structure of the firms with which the employees bargain. Another approach
has been to involve employees directly in corporate governance by, for example, providing
for employee representation on the firm’s board of directors. Although serious attention
was given to employee participation in corporate governance in Germany as early as the
Weimar Republic, unionism was the dominant approach everywhere until the Second
World War. Then, after the War, serious experimentation with employee participation in
corporate governance began in Europe. The results of this experimentation are most
conspicuous in Germany where, under legislation initially adopted for the coal and steel
industry in 1951 and extended by stages to the rest of German industry between 1952 and
1976, employees are entitled to elect half of the members of the (upper-tier) board of
directors in all large German firms. While this German form of “codetermination” has been
the most far-reaching experiment, a number of other European countries have also
experimented with employee participation in more modest ways, giving employees some
form of mandatory minority representation on the boards of large corporations.
Enthusiasm for employee participation crested in the 1970s with the radical
expansion of codetermination in Germany and the drafting of the European Community’s
proposed Fifth Directive on Company Law,7 under which German-style codetermination
would be extended throughout Europe. Employee participation also attracted
considerable attention in the U.S. during that period, as adversarial unionism began to
lose its appeal as a means of dealing with problems of labor contracting and, in fact,
began to disappear from the industrial scene.
Since then, worker participation in corporate governance has steadily lost power as
a normative ideal. Despite repeated watering-down, Europe’s Fifth Directive has never
become law, and it now seems highly unlikely that German-style codetermination will ever
be adopted elsewhere. The growing view today is that meaningful direct worker voting
participation in corporate affairs tends to produce inefficient decisions, paralysis, or weak
boards, and that these costs are likely to exceed any potential benefits that worker
participation might bring. The problem, at root, seems to be one of governance. While
8. Henry Hansmann, supra note 2, at 89-119; Henry Hansmann, Worker Participation
and Corporate Governance, 43 UNIVERSITY OF TORONTO LAW JOURNAL 589-606 (1993);
Henry Hansmann, Probleme von Kollektiventscheidungen und Theorie der Firma --
Folgerungen für die Arbeitnehmermitbestimmung, in Claus Ott and Hans-Bernd Sch?fer,
editors, ?KONOMISCHE ANALYSE DES UNTERNEHMENSRECHTS 287-305 (1993). On the
weaknesses of German boards, see, e.g., Mark Roe, German Securities Markets and
German Codetermination, 98 COLUMBIA BUSINESS LAW REVIEW 167 (1998).
9. Some commentators, of course, continue to see co-determination as a core
element of a unique Northern European form of corporate governance. See, e.g., Michel
Albert, CAPITALISM VS. CAPITALISM (1993) (asserting the superiority of the “Rhine Model”
of captialism over the “Anglo-Saxon Model”). Even Albert concedes, however, the growing
ideological power of shareholder-oriented corporate governance. Id. at 169 -190.
6
direct employee participation in corporate decision-making may mitigate some of the
inefficiencies that can beset labor contracting, the workforce in typical firms is too
heterogeneous in its interests to make an effective governing body – and the problems are
magnified greatly when employees must share governance with investors, as in
codetermined firms. In general, contractual devices, whatever their weaknesses, are
(when supplemented by appropriate labor market regulation) evidently superior to voting
and other collective choice mechanisms in resolving conflicts of interest among and
between a corporation’s investors and employees.8
Today, even inside Germany, few commentators argue for codetermination as a
general model for corporate law in other jurisdictions. Rather, codetermination now tends
to be defended in Germany as, at most, a workable adaptation to local interests and
circumstances or, even more modestly, as an experiment of questionable value that would
now be politically difficult to undo.9
C. The State-Oriented Model
Both before and after the Second World War, there was widespread support for a
corporatist system in which the government would play a strong direct role in the affairs of
large business firms to provide some assurance that private enterprise would serve the
public interest. Technocratic governmental bureaucrats, the theory went, would help to
avoid the deficiencies of the market through the direct exercise of influence in corporate
affairs. This approach was most extensively realized in post-war France and Japan. In the
United States, though there was little actual experimentation with this approach outside of
the defense industries, the model attracted considerable intellectual attention. Perhaps the
most influential exposition of the state-oriented model in the Anglo-American world was
Andrew Shonfield’s 1967 book Modern Capitalism, with its admiring description of
10. Andrew Shonfield, MODERN CAPITALISM: THE CHANGING BALANCE OF PUBLIC AND
PRIVATE POWER (1967).
7
French and Japanese style “indicative planning.”10 The strong performance of the
Japanese economy, and subsequently of other state-guided Asian economies, lent
substantial credibility to this model even through the 1980s.
The principal instruments of state control over corporate affairs in corporatist
economies have generally lain outside of corporate law. They include, for example,
substantial discretion in the hands of government bureaucrats over the allocation of credit,
foreign exchange, licenses, and exemptions from anticompetition rules. Nevertheless,
corporate law also played a role by, for example, weakening shareholder control over
corporate managers (to reduce pressures on managers that might operate counter to the
preferences of the state) and employing state-administered criminal sanctions rather than
shareholder-controlled civil lawsuits as the principal sanction for managerial malfeasance
(to give the state strong authority over managers that could be used at the government’s
discretion).
But the state-oriented model, too, has now lost most of its attraction. One reason is
the move away from state socialism in general as a popular intellectual and political model.
Important landmarks on this path include the rise of Thatcherism in England in the 1970s,
Mitterand’s abandonment of state ownership in France in the 1980s, and the sudden
collapse of communism nearly everywhere in the 1990s. The relatively poor performance
of the Japanese corporate sector after 1989, together with the more recent collapse of
other Asian economies that were organized on state corporatist lines, has now discredited
this model even further. Today, few would argue that giving the state a strong direct hand
in corporate affairs has much normative appeal.
D. Stakeholder Models
Over the past decade, the literature on corporate governance and corporate law
has sometimes advocated “stakeholder” models as a normatively attractive alternative to a
strongly shareholder-oriented view of the corporation. The stakeholders involved may be
employees, creditors, customers, merchants in a firm’s local community, or even broader
interest groups such as beneficiaries of a well-preserved environment. The stakeholders,
it is argued, will be subject to opportunistic exploitation by the firm and its shareholders if
corporate managers are accountable only to the firm’s shareholders; corporate law must
therefore assure that managers are responsive to stakeholder interests as well.
While stakeholder models start with a common problem, they posit two different
kinds of solutions. One group of stakeholder models looks to what we term a “fiduciary”
model of the corporation, in which the board of directors functions as a neutral coordinator
11. Margaret M. Blair & Lynn A. Stout, A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law,
85 VA. L. REV. 247 (1999)
12. Company Law Reform Steering Group, Modern Company Law for a Competitive
Environment: The Strategic Framework 39-46 (March 1999) (setting forth the alternatives
of maintaining the existing directorial duty of following enlightened shareholder interest or
reformulating a “pluralist” duty to all major stakeholders in order to encourage firm specific
investment.)
13. Reinhard H. Smith and Gerald Spindler, Path Dependence, Corporate
Governance and Complementarity – A Comment on Bebchuk and Roe, the Johann
Wolfgang Goethe-Universitat Working Paper Series in Finance and Accounting, No. 27
(1999), at p. 14.
8
of the contributions and returns of all stakeholders in the firm. Under this model,
stakeholders other than investors are not given direct representation on the corporate
board. Rather, these other stakeholders are to be protected by relaxing the board’s duty
or incentive to represent only the interests of shareholders, thus giving the board greater
discretion to look after other stakeholders’ interests.
The fiduciary model finds its most explicit recognition in U.S. law in the form of
constituency statutes that permit boards to consider the interests of constituencies other
than shareholders in mounting takeover defenses. Margaret Blair and Lynn Stout,
sophisticated American advocates of the fiduciary model, also claim to find support for this
normative model in other, broader aspects of U.S. corporate law.11 In the U.K., the
fiduciary model is a key element in the ongoing debate over the duties of corporate
directors.12
The second group of stakeholder models substitutes direct stakeholder
representatives for fiduciary directors. In this “representative” model of the corporation,
two or more stakeholder constituencies appoint representatives to the board of directors,
who then elaborate policies that maximize the joint welfare of all stakeholders, subject to
the bargaining leverage that each group brings to the boardroom table. In this case the
board functions ideally as a kind of collective fiduciary, even though its individual members
remain partisan representatives. The board of directors (or supervisory board) then
becomes an unmediated “coalition of stakeholder groups” and functions as “an arena for
cooperation with respect to the function of monitoring the management” as well as an
arena for resolving “conflicts with respect to the specific interests of different stakeholder
groups.”13
Neither the fiduciary nor the representative stakeholder models, however, constitute
at bottom a new approach to the corporation. Rather, despite the new rhetoric with which
the stakeholder models are presented, and the more explicit economic theorizing that
14. In a hoary debate that cross cuts jurisdictional boundaries, proponents of the view
that corporations exist by virtue of a state “concession” or privilege have also been
associated with the view that corporations ought to be governed in the interests of society
9
sometimes accompanies them, they are at heart just variants on the older manager-
oriented and labor-oriented models. Stakeholder models of the fiduciary type are in effect
just reformulations of the manager-oriented model, and suffer the same weaknesses.
While untethered managers may better serve the interests of some classes of
stakeholders, such as a firm’s existing employees and creditors, the managers’ own
interests will often come to have disproportionate salience in their decision-making, with
costs to some interest groups – such as shareholders, customers, and potential new
employees and creditors – that outweigh any gains to the stakeholders who are benefitted.
Moreover, the courts are evidently incapable of formulating and enforcing fiduciary duties
of sufficient refinement to assure that managers behave more efficiently and fairly.
Stakeholder models of the representative type, in turn, closely resemble yesterday’s
labor-oriented model -- though generalized to extend to other stakeholders as well -- and
are again subject to the same weaknesses. The mandatory inclusion of any set of
stakeholder representatives on the board is likely to impair corporate decision-making
processes with costly consequences that outweigh any gains to the groups that obtain
representation.
IV. THE SHAREHOLDER-ORIENTED (OR “STANDARD”) MODEL
With the abandonment of a privileged role for managers, employees, or the state in
corporate affairs, we are left today with a widespread normative consensus that
shareholders alone are the parties to whom corporate managers should be accountable.
A. In Whose Interest?
This is not to say that there is agreement that corporations should be run in the
interests of shareholders alone, much less that the law should sanction that result. All
thoughtful people believe that corporate enterprise should be organized and operated to
serve the interests of society as a whole, and that the interests of shareholders deserve no
greater weight in this social calculus than do the interests of any other members of society.
The point is simply that now, as a consequence of both logic and experience, there is
convergence on a consensus that the best means to this end -- the pursuit of aggregate
social welfare -- is to make corporate managers strongly accountable to shareholder
interests, and (at least in direct terms) only to those interests. It follows that even the
extreme proponents of the so-called “concession theory” of the corporation can embrace
the primacy of shareholder interests in good conscience.14
– or all corporate constituencies – rather than in the private interest of shareholders alone.
See, e.g., Dodd, supra note 5, at 1148-1150; Paul G. Mahoney, Contract or Concession?
A Historical Perspective on Business Corporations, Working Paper, University of Virginia
School of Law (1999). Conversely, proponents of the view that the corporation is a bottom
a contract among investors have tended to advance the primacy of shareholder interests in
corporate governance.
In our view the traditional debate between concession and contract theorists is
simply confused. On the one hand, corporations -- whether “concessions” or contracts --
should be regulated when it is the public interest to do so. On the other hand, the standard
model is, in effect, an assertion that social welfare is best served by encouraging
corporate managers to pursue shareholder interests.
10
Of course, asserting the primacy of shareholder interests in corporate law does not
imply that the interests of corporate stakeholders must or should go unprotected. It merely
indicates that the most efficacious legal mechanisms for protecting the interests of
nonshareholder constituencies -- or at least all constituencies other than creditors -- lie
outside of corporate law. For workers, this includes the law of labor contracting, pension
law, health and safety law, and antidiscrimination law. For consumers, it includes product
safety regulation, warranty law, tort law governing product liability, antitrust law, and
mandatory disclosure of product contents and characteristics. For the public at large, it
includes environmental law and the law of nuisance and mass torts.
Creditors, to be sure, are to some degree an exception. There remains general
agreement that corporate law should directly regulate some aspects of the relationship
between a business corporation and its creditors. Conspicuous examples include rules
governing veil-piercing and limits on the distribution of dividends in the presence of
inadequate capital. The reason for these rules, however, is that there are unique problems
of creditor contracting that are integral to the corporate form, owing principally to the
presence of limited liability as a structural characteristic of that form. These types of rules,
however, are modest in scope. They do not -- outside of bankruptcy -- involve creditors in
corporate governance, but rather are confined to limiting shareholders’ ability to use the
characteristics of the corporate form opportunistically to exploit creditors.
B. Which Shareholders?
The shareholder-oriented model does more than assert the primacy of shareholder
interests, however. It asserts the interests of all shareholders, including minority
shareholders. More particularly, it is a central tenet in the standard model that minority or
noncontrolling shareholders should receive strong protection from exploitation at the hands
of controlling shareholders. In publicly-traded firms, this means that all shareholders should
be assured an essentially equal claim on corporate earnings and assets.
11
There are two conspicuous reasons for this approach, both of which are rooted in
efficiency concerns. One reason is that, absent credible protection for noncontrolling
shareholders, business corporations will have difficulty raising capital from the equity
markets. The second reason is that the devices by which controlling shareholders divert to
themselves a disproportionate share of corporate benefits commonly involve inefficient
investment choices and management policies.
C. The Import of Ownership Structure
It is sometimes said that the shareholder-oriented model of corporate law is well
suited only to those jurisdictions, such as the U.S. and the UK, in which one finds large
numbers of firms with widely dispersed shareownership. A different model is appropriate,
it is said, for those jurisdictions, such as the nations of continental Europe, in which
ownership is more concentrated.
This view is unconvincing, however. Closely-held corporations, like publicly-held
corporations, operate most efficiently when the law helps assure that managers are
primarily responsive to shareholder interests, and helps assure as well that controlling
shareholders do not opportunistically exploit noncontrolling shareholders. The shareholder
primacy model does not logically privilege any particular ownership structure. Indeed, both
concentrated and dispersed shareholdings have been celebrated, at different times and by
different commentators, for their ability to advance shareholder interests in the face of
serious agency problems. Equally important, every jurisdiction includes a range of
corporate ownership structures. While both the U.S. and U.K. have many large firms with
dispersed ownership, both countries also contain a far larger number of corporations that
are closely held. Similarly, every major Continental European jurisdiction has at least a
handful of firms with dispersed ownership, and the number of such firms is evidently
growing. It follows that every jurisdiction must have a system of corporate law that is
adequate to handle the full range of ownership structures.
V. COMPETITIVE PRESSURES TOWARD CONVERGENCE
The shareholder-oriented model has emerged as the normative consensus, not just
because of the failure of the alternatives, but because important economic forces have
made the virtues of that model increasingly salient. There are, broadly speaking, three
ways in which a model of corporate governance can come to be recognized as superior:
by force of logic, by force of example, and by force of competition. The emerging
consensus in favor of the standard model has, in recent years, been driven with increasing
intensity by each of these forces. We examine them here in turn.
12
A. The Force of Logic
An important source of the success of the standard model is that, in recent years,
scholars and other commentators in law, economics, and business have developed
persuasive reasons to believe that this model offers greater efficiencies than the principal
alternatives.
One of these reasons is that, in most circumstances, the interests of equity
investors in the firm -- the firm’s residual claimants -- cannot be adequately protected by
contract. Rather, to protect their interests, they must be given the right to control the firm.
A second reason is that, if the control rights granted to the firm’s equityholders are
exclusive and strong, they will have powerful incentives to maximize the value of the firm.
And a third reason is that the interests of participants in the firm other than shareholders
can generally be adequately protected by contract and regulation, so that maximization of
the firm’s value by its shareholders complements the interests of those other participants
rather than competing with them.
This reasoning is today reflected in much of the current literature on corporate
finance and the economics of the firm – a literature that is becoming increasingly
international. The consequence is to highlight the economic case for the shareholder-
oriented model of governance. In addition, the persuasive power of the standard model
has been amplified through its acceptance by a worldwide network of corporate
intermediaries, including international law firms, the big five accounting firms, and the
principal investment banks and consulting firms – a network whose rapidly expanding
scale and scope today gives it exceptional influence in diffusing the standard model of
shareholder-centered corporate governance.
B. The Force of Example
The second source of the success of the standard model of corporate governance
is the economic performance of jurisdictions in which it predominates. A simple
comparison across countries adhering to different models – at least in very recent years –
lends credence to the view that adherence to the standard model promotes better
economic outcomes. The developed common law jurisdictions have performed well in
comparison to the principal East Asian and continental European countries, which are less
in alignment with the standard model. The principal examples include, of course, the
strong performance of the American economy in comparison with the weaker economic
performance of the German, Japanese, and French economies.
One might, to be sure, object that the success of the shareholder-oriented model is
quite recent and will perhaps prove to be ephemeral, and that the apparent normative
consensus based on that success will be ephemeral as well. After all, only fifteen years
ago many thought that Japanese and German firms, which were clearly not organized on
15. To be fair, however, American commentators tended to praise corporate
governance in Germany and Japan in the name of the shareholder model. Thus it was the
purported ability of German banks to monitor managers and correctly value long term
business projects that caught the eye of American commentators after the 1970s, not co-
determination and the labor-oriented model of the firm. See, e.g., Michael T. Jacobs,
SHORT-TERM AMERICA: THE CAUSES AND CURES OF OUR BUSINESS MYOPIA (1991).
16. Indirect evidence to this effect comes from international surveys such as a recent
international survey of top managers conducted by the FINANCIAL TIMES to determine the
world’s most respected companies. Four of the top five most respected companies were
American, and hence operated under the shareholder model (the fifth was Daimler-
Chrysler, which is “almost” American for these purposes). Similarly, 29 of the top 40 firms
were either American or British. See World’s Most Respected Companies, Financial
Times Web Site (December 17, 1999).
17. See, e.g., Roman Frydman, Marek Hessel, and Andrzej Rapacyznski, Why
Ownership Matters? Entrepreneurship and the Restructuring of Enterprises in Central
Europe (Working Paper, April 1988) (firms privatized to outside owners proved superior to
state firms and firms privatized to workers or previous managers in new market
development).
13
the shareholder-oriented model, were winning the competition, and that this was because
they had adopted a superior form of corporate governance.15 But this is probably a
mistaken interpretation of the nature of the economic competition in recent decades, and
is surely at odds with today’s prevailing opinion. The competition of the 1960s, 70s, and
early 80s was in fact among Japanese state-oriented corporations, German labor-oriented
corporations, and American manager-oriented corporations. It was not until the late 1980s
that one could speak of widespread international competition from shareholder-oriented
firms.
C. The Force of Competition
The increasing internationalization of both product and financial markets has
brought individual firms from jurisdictions adhering to different models in direct
competition. It is now widely thought that in these more direct encounters, too, firms
organized under the shareholder-oriented model have had the upper hand.16
Firms organized and operated according to the standard model can be expected to
have important competitive advantages over firms adhering more closely to other models.
These advantages include access to equity capital at lower cost (including, conspicuously,
start-up capital), more aggressive development of new product markets,17 stronger
incentives to reorganize along lines that are managerially coherent, and more rapid
18. In this regard it should be noted that small and medium-sized firms in every
jurisdiction are organized under legal regimes consistent with the standard model. Thus,
shareholders – and shareholders alone -- select the members of supervisory board in the
vast majority of (smaller) German and Dutch firms. These jurisdictions impose alternative
labor- or manager-oriented regimes only on a minority of comparatively large firms.
14
abandonment of inefficient investments.
These competitive advantages do not always imply that firms governed by the
standard model will displace those governed by an alternative model in the course of firm-
to-firm competition, for two reasons. First, firms operating under the standard model may
be no more efficient than other firms in many respects. For example, state-oriented
Japanese and Korean companies have demonstrated great efficiency in the management
and expansion of standardized production processes, while German and Dutch firms such
as Daimler Benz and Philips (operating under labor- and management-oriented
respectively) have been widely recognized for engineering prowess and technical
innovation.
Second, even when firms governed by the standard model are clearly more efficient
than their nonstandard competitors, the cost-conscious standard-model firms may be
forced to abandon particular markets for precisely that reason. Less efficient firms
organized under alternative models may overinvest in capacity or accept abnormally low
returns on their investments in general, and thereby come to dominate a product market by
underpricing their profit-maximizing competitors.
But if the competitive advantages of standard-model firms do not necessarily force
the displacement of nonstandard firms in established markets, these standard-model firms
are likely to achieve a disproportionate share among start-up firms, in new product
markets, and in industries that are in the process of rapid change.18
The ability of standard-model firms to expand rapidly in growth industries is
magnified, moreover, by access to institutional investors and the international equity
markets, which understandably prefer shareholder-oriented governance and are influential
advocates of the standard model. Over time, then, the standard model is likely to win the
competitive struggle on the margins, confining other governance models to older firms and
mature product markets. As the pace of technological change continues to quicken, this
competitive advantage should continue to increase.
VI. THE RISE OF THE SHAREHOLDER CLASS
In tandem with the competitive forces just described, a final source of ideological
19. Stock market capitalization as a percentage of GDP has risen dramatically in
virtually every major jurisdiction over the past 20 years. In most European countries, the
increase has been by a factor of three or four. School Brief: Stocks in Trade, THE
ECONOMIST, Novermber 13, 1999, at pp. 85-86.
20. Carolyn Kay Brancato et al., INSTITUTIONAL INVESTOR CONCENTRATION OF ECONOMIC
POWER AND VOTING AUTHORITY IN U.S. PUBLICLY HELD CORPORATIONS (Sept. 12, 1991)
(unpublished study).
21. Latin America offers a telling example. In 1981, Chile became the first country in
the region to set up a system of private pension funds. By 1995, Argentina, Colombia, and
Peru had done the same. By 1996, a total of $108 billion was under management in Latin
American pension funds, which by then had come to play an important role in the
development of the local equity markets. It was estimated, in 1997, that total assets would
grow to $200 billion by 2000, and to $600 billion by 2011. Save Amigo Save, THE
ECONOMIST, December 9, 1995, at S15; A Private Affair, LATIN FINANCE, December 1998,
15
convergence on the standard model is a fundamental realignment of interest group
structures in developed economies. At the center of this realignment is the emergence of
a public shareholder class as a broad and powerful interest group in both corporate and
political affairs across jurisdictions.
There are two elements to this realignment. The first is the rapid expansion of the
ownership of equity securities within broad segments of society, creating a coherent
interest group that presents an increasingly strong countervailing force to the organized
interests of managers, employees, and the state. The second is the shift in power, within
this expanding shareholder class, in favor of the interests of minority and noncontrolling
shareholders over those of inside or controlling shareholders.
A. The Diffusion of Equity Ownership
Stock ownership is becoming more pervasive everywhere.19 No longer is it
confined to a very small group of wealthy citizens.
In the United States, this diffusion of shareownership has been underway since the
beginning of the twentieth century. It has accelerated substantially in recent years,
however. Since the Second World War, an ever-increasing number of American workers
have had their savings invested in corporate equities through pension funds. Over the
same period, the mutual fund industry has also expanded rapidly, becoming the repository
of an ever-increasing share of nonpension savings for the population at large.20 Similarly,
in Europe and Japan, and to some extent elsewhere, we have begun to see parallel
developments, as markets for equity securities have become more developed.21
at 6; Stephen Fidler, Chile’s Crusader for the Cause, FINANCIAL TIMES, March 14, 1997.
22. See Stewart J. Schwarn and Randall S. Thomas, Realigning Corporate
Governance: Shareholder Activism by Labor Unions, in S. Estreicher, ed., EMPLOYEE
REPRESENTATION IN THE EMERGING WORKPLACE: ALTERNATIVES/SUPPLEMENTS TO
COLLECTIVE BARGAINING (1998).
23. See, e.g., Greg Steinmetz and Michael R. Sesit, Rising U.S. Investment in
European Equities Galvanizes Old World, WALL STREET JOURNAL, Aug. 4, 1999 at pp.A1
& A8 (U.S. investors sparking important governance changes in large European
companies).
16
The growing wealth of developed societies is a major factor underlying these
changes. Even blue-collar workers now often have sufficient personal savings to justify
investment in equity securities. No longer do labor and capital constitute clearly distinct
interest groups in society. Workers, through shareownership, are coming increasingly to
share the economic interests of other equityholders. Indeed, in the United States, union
pension funds are today quite active in pressing the view that companies must be
managed in the best interests of their shareholders.22
B. The Shift in Balance Toward Public Shareholders
As the example of the activist union pension funds suggests, diffusion of
shareownership is only one aspect of the rise of the shareholder class. Another aspect is
the new prominence of substantial institutions that have interests coincident with those of
public shareholders and that are prepared to articulate and defend those interests.
Institutional investors, such as pension funds and mutual funds -- which are particularly
prominent in the U.S., though now rapidly growing elsewhere as well -- are the most
conspicuous examples of these institutions. Associations of minority investors in
European countries provide another example. These institutions not only give effective
voice to shareholder interest, but promote in particular the interests of dispersed public
shareholders rather than those of controlling shareholders or corporate insiders. The result
is that ownership of equity among the public at large, while broader than ever, is at the
same time gaining more effective voice in corporate affairs.
Morever, the new activist shareholder-oriented institutions are today acting
increasingly on an international scale. As a consequence, their influence now reaches well
beyond their home jurisdictions.23 We now have not only a common ideology supporting
shareholder-oriented corporate law, but also an organized interest group to press that
ideology – and an interest group that is broad, diverse, and increasingly international in its
membership.
24. Of particular interest are signs of change in the cross-ownership networks among
major German and Japanese firms. New legislation proposed by the German government
would eliminate the heavy (up to 60%) capital gains taxes on corporate sales of stock,
which is expected to result in widespread dissolution of block holdings. Haig Simonian,
Germany to abolish tax of disposal of cross-holdings, FINANCIAL TIMES, Dec. 24, 1999, at
p. 1. In Japan keiretsu structures are beginning to unwind as a result of bank mergers and
competitive pressure to seek higher returns on capital. Paul Abrahams and Gillian Tett,
The circle is broken, FINANCIAL TIMES, Nov. 9, 1999, at p. 18.
17
In the U.S., the principal effect of the expansion and empowerment of the
shareholder class has been to shift interest group power to shareholders from managers.
In Europe and Japan, the more important effect has been to shift power from workers and
the state and, increasingly, from dominant shareholders.24
VII. CONVERGENCE OF GOVERNANCE PRACTICES
Thus far we have attempted to explain the sources of ideological convergence on
the standard model of corporate governance. Our principal argument is on this normative
level: we make the claim that no important competitors to the standard model of corporate
governance remain persuasive today. This claim is consistent with significant differences
among jurisdictions in corporate practice and law over the short run: ideological
convergence does not necessarily mean rapid convergence in practice. There are many
potential obstacles to rapid institutional convergence, even when there is general
consensus on what constitutes best practice. Nevertheless, we believe that the developing
ideological consensus on the standard model will have important implications for the
convergence of practice and law over the long run.
We expect that the reform of corporate governance practices will generally precede
the reform of corporate law, for the simple reason that governance practice is largely a
matter of private ordering that does not require legislative action. Recent developments in
most developed jurisdictions -- and in many developing ones -- bear out this prediction.
Under the influence of the ideological and interest group changes discussed above,
corporate governance reform has already become the watchword not only in North
America but also in Europe and Japan. Corporate actors are themselves implementing
structural changes to bring their firms closer to the standard model. In the U.S., these
changes include appointment of larger numbers of independent directors to boards of
directors, reduction in overall board size, development of powerful board committees
dominated by outsiders (such as audit committees, compensation committees, and
nominating committees), closer links between management compensation and the value
18
of the firm’s equity securities, and strong communication between board members and
institutional shareholders. In Europe and Japan, many of the same changes are taking
place, though with a lag. Examples range from the OECD’s promulgation of new
principles of corporate governance, to recent decisions by Japanese companies to reduce
board sizes and include non-executive directors (following the lead of Sony), to the rapid
diffusion of stock option compensation plans for top managers in the U.K. and in the
principal commercial jurisdictions of Continental Europe.
VIII. LEGAL CONVERGENCE
Not surprisingly, convergence in the fine structure of corporate law proceeds more
slowly than convergence in governance practices. Legal change requires legislative
action. Nevertheless, we expect shareholder pressure (and the power of shareholder-
oriented ideology) to force gradual legal changes, largely but not entirely in the direction of
Anglo-American corporate and securities law. There are already important indications of
evolutionary convergence in the realms of board structure, securities regulation and
accounting methodologies, and even the regulation of takeovers.
A. Board Structure
With respect to board structure, convergence has been in the direction of a legal
regime that strongly favors a single-tier board that is relatively small and has a substantial
complement of outside directors, but contains insiders as well. Mandatory two-tier board
structures seem a thing of the past; the weaker and less responsive boards that they
promote are justified principally as a complement to worker codetermination, and thus
share – indeed, constitute one of – the weaknesses of the latter institution. The declining
fortunes of the two-tier board are reflected in the evolution of the European Union’s
Proposed Regulation on the Statute for a European Company. When originally drafted in
1970, that Regulation called for a mandatory two-tier board. In 1991, however, the
Proposed Regulation was amended to permit member states to prescribe either a two-tier
or a single-tier system. Meanwhile, on the practical side, France, which made provision for
an optional two-tier board when the concept was more in vogue, has seen few of its
corporations adopt the device.
At the same time, jurisdictions that traditionally favored the opposite extreme of
insider-dominated, single-tier boards have come to accept a significant complement of
outside directors. In the U.S., independent directors have long been mandated by the New
York Stock Exchange listing rules to serve on the important audit committees of listed
firms, while more recently state law doctrine has created a strong role for outside directors
in approving transactions where interests might be conflicted. In Japan, a similar evolution
may be foreshadowed by the recent movement among Japanese companies, mentioned
above, toward smaller boards and independent directors, and by the recent publication of
25. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE PRINCIPLES: FINAL REPORT, Corporate Governance
Committee of the Corporate Governance Forum of Japan (May 26, 1998).
26. This can be seen, for example, by comparing the EU’s Listing Particulars Directive
with the SEC’s Form S-1 for the registration of securities under the 1933 Act. If U.S.
disclosure requirements remain more aggressive, it must be remembered that the EU
Directives establish minimal requirements that member states can and do supplement.
See John C. Coffee, The Future as History: The Prospects for Global Convergence in
Corporate Governance and its Implications, 93 NW. U. L. REV. 641 (1999). See generally
Amir N. Licht, International Diversity in Securities Regulation: Roadblocks on the Way to
Convergence, 20 CARDOZO LAW REVIEW 227 (1998) (discussing convergence in
disclosure rules, accounting standards, and corporate governance).
19
a code of corporate governance principles advocating these reforms by a committee of
leading Japanese managers.25 The result is convergence from both ends toward the
middle: while two-tier boards themselves seem to be on the way out, countries with single-
tier board structures are incorporating, in their regimes, one of the strengths of the typical
two-tier board regime, namely the substantial role it gives to independent (outside)
directors.
B. Disclosure and Capital Market Regulation
Regulation of routine disclosure to shareholders, intended to aid in policing
corporate managers, is also converging conspicuously. Without seeking to examine this
complex field in detail here, we note that major jurisdictions outside of the U.S. are
reinforcing their disclosure systems, while the U.S. has been retreating from some of the
more inexplicably burdensome of its federal regulations, such as the highly restrictive proxy
solicitation rules that until recently crippled communication among American institutional
investors. Indeed, the subject matter of mandatory disclosure for public companies is
startlingly similar across the major commercial jurisdictions today.26
Similarly, uniform accounting standards are rapidly crystallizing out of the babel of
national rules and practices into two well defined sets of international standards: the
GAAP accounting rules administered by the Financial Auditing Standards Board in the
U.S., and the International Accounting Standards administered by the International
Accounting Standards Committee in London. While important differences remain between
the competing sets of international standards, these differences are far smaller than the
variations among the national accounting methodologies that preceded GAAP and the
new International Standards. The two international standards, moreover, are likely to
converge further, if only because of the economic savings that would result from a single
27. See, e.g., Elizabeth MacDonald, U.S. Accounting Board Faults Global Rules,
WALL STREET JOURNAL, Oct. 18, 1999, at 1.
28. Theodor Baums, Corporate Governance in Germany: System and Current
Developments, Working Paper, Universitat Osnabruck (1999).
29. Already Europe has seen a remarkable wave of takeovers in 1999, culminating in
what may be the largest hostile takeover attempt in history: Vodaphone’s effort to acquire
Mannesmann. In addition, many established jurisdictions are adopting rules to regulate
tender offers that bear a family resemblance to the Williams Act or to the rules of the
London City Code. See, e.g., Brazil’s tender offer regulations, Securities Commission
Ruling 69, Sept. 8. 1987. Arts. 1-4; and Italy’s recently adopted reform of takeover
regulation, Legislative Decree 58 of February 24, 1999 (the so-called “Draghi Reform”).
20
set of global accounting standards.27
C. Shareholder Suits
Shareholder initiated suits against directors and managers are now being
accommodated in countries that had previously rendered them ineffective. Germany has
recently reduced the ownership threshold qualifying shareholders to demand legal action
against managing directors (to be brought by the supervisory board or special company
representative) from a 10% equity stake to the lesser of a five percent stake or a 1 million
DM stake when there is suspicion of dishonesty or illegality.28 Japan has altered its rules
on attorneys’ fees to create meaningful incentives for litigation. At the same time, U.S. law
is moving toward the center from the other direction by beginning to rein in the country’s
strong incentives for potentially opportunistic litigation. At the federal level, there are
recently-strengthened pleading requirements upon initiation of shareholder actions, new
safe harbors for forward-looking company projections, and recent provision for lead
shareholders to take control in class actions. State law rules, meanwhile, are making it
easier for a corporation to get a shareholders’ suit dismissed.
D. Takeovers
Finally, regulation of takeovers also seems headed for convergence. As it is,
current differences in takeover regulation are more apparent than real. Hostile takeovers
are rare outside the Anglo-American jurisdictions, principally owing to the more
concentrated patterns of shareholdings outside those jurisdictions. As shareholding
patterns become more homogeneous (as we expect they will), and as corporate culture
everywhere becomes more accommodating of takeovers (as it seems destined to),
takeovers will presumably become much more common in Europe, Japan, and
elsewhere.29
21
Moreover, where operative legal constraints on takeovers in fact differ, they show
signs of convergence. In particular, for several decades the U.S. has been increasing its
regulation of takeovers, placing additional constraints both on the ability of acquirers to act
opportunistically and on the ability of incumbent managers to entrench themselves or
engage in self-dealing. With the widespread diffusion of the “poison pill” defense, and the
accompanying limits that courts have placed on the use of that defense, partial hostile
tender offers of a coercive character are a thing of the past -- a result similar to that which
European jurisdictions have accomplished with a “mandatory bid rule” requiring acquirers
of control to purchase all shares in their target companies at a single price.
To be sure, jurisdictions diverge in other aspects of takeover law, where the points
of convergence are still uncertain. For example, American directors enjoy far more latitude
to defend against hostile takeovers than do directors in most European jurisdictions.
Under current Delaware law, incumbent boards have authority to resist hostile offers
although they remain to vulnerable to bids that are tied to proxy fights at shareholders
meetings. As the incidence of hostile takeovers increases in Europe, then, European
jurisdictions may incline toward Delaware by permitting additional defensive tactics.
Alternatively, given the dangers of managerial entrenchment, Delaware may move toward
European norms by limiting defensive tactics more severely. While we cannot predict
where the equilibrium point will lie, it is a reasonable conjecture that the law on both sides
of the Atlantic will ultimately converge on a single regime.
E. Judicial Discretion
There remains one very general aspect of corporate law on which one might feel
that convergence will be slow to come: the degree of judicial discretion in resolving
disputes among corporate actors ex post. Such discretion has long been much more
conspicuous in the common law jurisdictions, and particularly in the U.S., than in the civil
law jurisdictions.
But, even here, there is good reason to believe that there will be strong
convergence across systems over time. Civil law jurisdictions, whether in the form of court
decision-making or arbitration, seems to be moving toward a more discretionary model.
At the same time, there are signs that the U.S. is moving away from the more extreme
forms of unpredictable ex post decision-making that have sometimes been characteristic
of, say, the Delaware courts. U.S. securities law is civilian in spirit and elaborated by
detailed rules promulgated by the Securities Exchange Commission (SEC). And the
Corporate Governance Project of the American Law Institute offers a code-like
systematization of substantive state corporate law, including even the notoriously vague
and open-ended U.S. case law that articulates the fiduciary duties of loyalty and care.
30. Lucian Bebchuk and Mark Roe, A Theory of Path Dependence in Corporate
Ownership and Governance, forthcoming 52 STANFORD LAW REVIEW 127 (1999).
22
IX. POTENTIAL OBSTACLES TO CONVERGENCE
To be sure, important interests are threatened by movement toward the standard
model, and those interests can be expected to serve as a brake on change. We doubt,
however, that such interests will be able to stave off for long the reforms called for by the
growing ideological consensus focused on the standard model.
To take one example, consider the argument, prominently made by Lucian Bebchuk
and Mark Roe,30 that the private value extracted by corporate controllers (controlling
shareholders or powerful managers) will long serve as a barrier to the evolution of efficient
ownership structures, governance practices, and corporate law.
The essential structure of the Bebchuk and Roe argument is as follows: In
jurisdictions lacking strong protection for minority shareholders, controlling shareholders
divert to themselves a disproportionate share of corporate cash flows. The controlling
shareholders thus have an incentive to avoid any change in their firm’s ownership or
governance, or in the regulation to which their firm is subject, that would force them to
share the corporation’s earnings more equitably. Moreover, these corporate insiders have
the power, in many jurisdictions, to prevent such changes. Their position as controlling
shareholders permits them to block changes in the firm’s ownership structure merely by
refusing to sell their shares. Their position also permits them to block changes in
governance by selecting the firm’s directors. And, in those societies in which – as in most
of Europe – closely controlled firms dominate the economy, the wealth and collective
political weight of controlling shareholders permits them to block legal reforms that would
compromise their disproportionate private returns.
But this pessimistic view seems unwarranted. If, as the developing consensus view
holds, the standard shareholder-oriented governance model maximizes corporate value,
controlling shareholders who are motivated chiefly by economic considerations may not
wish to retain control of their firms. And, even if nonmonetary considerations lead insiders
to retain control, the economic significance of firms dominated by these insiders is likely to
diminish over time both in their own jurisdictions and in the world market.
A. Transactions To Capture Surplus
First, consider the case of controlling shareholders (“controllers”) who wish to
maximize their financial returns. Suppose that the prevailing legal regime permits
controlling shareholders to extract large private benefits from which public shareholders
are excluded. Predictably these controllers will sell their shares only if they receive a
31. See Lucian Bebchuk, Reinier Kraakman, and George Triantis, Stock Pyramids,
Cross-Ownership, and Dual Class Equity: The Creation and Agency Costs of Separating
Control from Cash Flow Rights, NBER Working Paper No. 6951 (1999).
23
premium price that captures the value of their private benefits, and they will reject any
corporate governance reform that reduces the value of those returns. That such controllers
will prefer to increase their own returns over increasing returns to the corporation does not
imply, however, that they will reject governance institutions or ownership structures that
maximize firm value. Bebchuk and Roe are too quick to conclude that controllers cannot
themselves profit by facilitating efficient governance.
Controllers who extract large private benefits from public companies are likely to
indulge in two forms of inefficient management. First, they may select investment projects
that maximize their own private returns over returns to the firm. For example, a controller
might select a less profitable investment project over a more profitable one precisely
because it offers opportunities for lucrative self-dealing. Second, controllers are likely to
have a preference for retaining and reinvesting earnings over distributing them, even when
it is inefficient to do so. The reason is that formal corporate distributions must be shared
with minority shareholders, while earnings reinvested in the firm remain available for
subsequent conversion into private benefits -- for example, through self-dealing
transactions. A controller’s incentive to engage in both forms of inefficient behavior
increases rapidly, moreover, if -- as has been common in Europe -- she employs devices
such as stock pyramids, corporate cross-holdings, and dual class stock to maintain a lock
on voting control while reducing her proportionate equity stake.31
Where law enforcement is effective, however, inefficient behavior itself creates
strong financial incentives to pursue more efficient ownership and governance structures.
When share prices are sufficiently depressed, anyone -- including controllers themselves --
can generate net gains by introducing more efficient governance structures. It follows that
controllers who can capture most or all of the value of these efficiency gains stand to profit
privately even more than they profit by extracting non-pro-rata benefits from poorly
governed firms. Controllers can capture these efficiency gains, moreover, in at least two
ways: (1) by selling out at a premium price reflecting potential efficiency gains to a buyer
or group of buyers who is willing and able to operate under nonexploitative governance
rules; or (2) by buying up minority shares (at depressed prices), and either managing their
firms as sole owners, or reselling their entire firms to buyers with efficient ownership
structures.
For controllers to extract these efficiency gains, however, efficient restructuring must
be legally possible: that is, the legal regime must offer means by which restructured firms
can commit to good governance practices. This can be done several ways without
threatening the private returns of controllers who have not yet undertaken to restructure.
24
One solution is an optional corporate and securities law regime that is dedicated -- or at
least more dedicated -- to protecting minority shareholders than the prevailing regime. For
example, firms can be permitted to list their shares on foreign exchanges with more
rigorous shareholder-protection rules. Another solution is simply to enforce shareholder-
protective provisions written into a restructured firm’s articles of incorporation.
It follows that even financially self-interested controllers have an incentive to promote
the creation of legal regimes in which firms at least have a choice of forming along efficient
lines – which, as we have argued, today means along shareholder-oriented lines. And,
once such an (optional) efficient regime has been established, and many of the existing
exploitative firms have taken advantage of the regime to profit from an efficient
restructuring, there should be a serious reduction in the size of the interest group that
wishes even to maintain as an option the old regime’s accommodation of firms that are
exploitative toward noncontrolling shareholders.
Bebchuk and Roe appear to assume that such developments will not occur
because the law will inhibit controlling shareholders from seeking efficient restructuring by
forcing them to share any gains from the restructuring equitably with noncontrolling
shareholders. But it is more plausible to suppose that the law will allow controlling
shareholders to claim the gains associated with an efficient restructuring -- by means of
techniques such as freezeout mergers and coercive tender offers – in jurisdictions where
controllers are able to extract large private benefits from ordinary corporate operations.
In short, if current controlling shareholders are interested just in maximizing their
financial returns, we can expect substantial pressure toward the adoption of efficient law.
B. Controllers Who Wish to Build Empires
Controlling shareholders do not always, however, wish to maximize their financial
returns. Rather -- and we suspect this is often true in Europe -- they may also seek
nonpecuniary returns.
For example, a controlling shareholder may wish simply to be on top of the largest
corporate empire possible, and therefore be prepared to overinvest in building market
share by selling at a price too low to maximize returns while reinvesting all available returns
in expanded capacity and R & D. Alternatively, a controller may be willing to accept a low
financial return in order to indulge a taste for a wide range of other costly practices, from
putting incompetent family members in positions of responsibility to preserving quasi-
feudal relations with employees and their local communities. Such practices may even be
efficient, if the controller values his nonpecuniary returns more than he would the monetary
returns that are given up. But, where the controller shares ownership with noncontrolling
shareholders who do not value the nonpecuniary returns, there is the risk that the controlling
shareholder will exploit the noncontrolling shareholders by refusing to distribute the firm’s
25
earnings and instead reinvesting those earnings in low-return projects that are valued
principally by the controller. (This can, of course, happen only where the controllers have
been able to mislead the noncontrolling shareholders somehow. If the latter shareholders
purchased their shares knowing that they would not have control, and that the controllers
would divert a share of returns to themselves through inefficient investments, then they
presumably paid a price for the shares that was discounted to reflect this diversion, leaving
the noncontrolling shareholders with a market rate of return on their investment.)
Efficiency-enhancing control transactions of the type described above may have
little to offer controlling shareholders of this type, since the restructuring may require that
they give up control of the firm, and hence give up not only the nonpecuniary returns they
were purchasing for themselves with the noncontrolling shareholder’s money, but also the
nonpecuniary returns they were purchasing with their own share of the firm’s invested
capital. Thus, controlling shareholders who value nonpecuniary gains will have less
incentive than purely financially-motivated controllers to favor efficient corporate legal
structures.
Moreover, inefficient firms with such controllers may survive quite nicely in
competitive markets, and in fact expand, despite their inefficiencies. For example, if the
controllers place value only on the size of the firm they control, they will continue to reinvest
in expansion so long as the return offered simply exceeds zero, with the result that they can
and will take market share from competing firms that are managed much more efficiently
but must pay their shareholders a market rate of return.
Jurisdictions with large numbers of firms dominated by controllers with
nonpecuniary motivations will, therefore, feel relatively less pressure than other jurisdictions
to adopt standard-model corporate law. Yet even in those jurisdictions -- which may
include much of Western Europe today -- the pressure for moving toward the standard
model is likely to grow irresistibly strong in the relatively near future. We briefly explore
here several reasons for this.
C. The Insiders’ Political Clout Will Be Insufficient to Protect Them
To begin with, the low profitability of firms that pursue nonpecuniary returns is likely
to select against their owners as controllers of industry. As long as the owners of these
firms subsidize low-productivity practices, they become progressively poorer relative to
investors in new businesses and owners of established firms who seek either to enhance
shareholder value or to sell out to others who will, with the result that economic and political
influence will shift to the latter.
Furthermore, the success of firms following shareholder-oriented governance
practices is likely to undermine political support for alternative models of corporate
governance for two reasons. One reason is that -- as we have suggested above -- the rise
26
of a shareholder class with growing wealth creates an interest group to press for reforming
corporate governance to encourage value-enhancing practices and restrain controlling
shareholders from extracting private benefits. Companies, whether domestic or foreign,
that attract public shareholders and pension funds by promising a better bottom line also
create natural enthusiasts for law reform and the standard model.
The second reason for a decline in the appeal of alternative styles of corporate
governance is the broader phenomenon of ideological convergence on the standard
model. Where previous ideologies may have celebrated the noblesse oblige of quasi-
feudal family firms or the industrial prowess of huge conglomerates ruled by insiders, the
increasing salience of the standard model makes empire building and domination
suspect, and the extraction of private value at the expense of minority shareholders
illegitimate, in everyone’s eyes. Costly governance practices therefore become
increasingly hard to sustain politically. Viewed through the lens of the new ideology, the old
practices are not only inefficient but also unjust, since they deprive ordinary citizens,
including pensioners and small investors, of a fair return on their investments. As civil
society grows more democratic, the privileged returns of controlling shareholders, leading
families, and entrenched managers become increasingly suspect.
Indeed, we expect that the social values that make it so prestigious for families to
control corporate empires in many countries will change importantly in the years to come.
The essentially feudal norms we now see in many patterns of industrial ownership will be
displaced by social values that place greater weight on social egalitarianism and individual
entrepreneurship, with the result that there is an ever-dwindling group of firms dominated
by controllers who place great weight on the nonpecuniary returns from presiding
personally over a corporate fiefdom.
D. The Insiders Who Preserve Their Firms and Legal Protections Will Become
Increasingly Irrelevant
Finally, even if dominant corporate controllers successfully block reform for some
period of time in any given jurisdiction, they are likely to become increasingly irrelevant in
the domestic economy, the world economy, or both.
At home, as we have already noted, the terms on which public equity capital
becomes available to finance new firms and new product markets are likely to be
dominated by the standard model. Venture capital investments and initial public offerings
are unlikely to occur if minority investors are not offered significant protection. This
protection can be provided without disturbing the older established firms by establishing
separate standard-model institutions that apply only to new firms. An example of this is the
Neuer Markt in the Frankfurt Stock Exchange, which provides the additional protection of
enhanced disclosure and GAAP accounting standards for investors in start-up companies
in search of equity capital, while leaving the less rigorous older rules in place for already-
32. See, e.g., John C. Coffee, supra note 26; Edward Rock, Mandatory Disclosure as
Credible Commitment: Going Public, Opting in, Opting Out, and Globalization, (Working
Paper, September 1998).
27
established firms.
Moreover, to the extent that domestic law or domestic firms fail to provide adequate
protections for public shareholders, other jurisdictions can supply the protection of the
standard model. Investment capital can flow to other countries and to foreign firms that do
business in the home jurisdiction. Alternatively, domestic companies may be able to
reincorporate in foreign jurisdictions or bind themselves to comply with the shareholder
protections offered by foreign law by listing on a foreign exchange (as some Israeli firms
now do by listing on NASDAQ).32
Through devices such as these that effectively permit new firms to adopt a model
that differs from that applicable to old firms, the national law and governance practices that
protect controlling insiders in established firms can be maintained without crippling the
national economy. The result is to partition off, and grandfather in, the older family-
controlled or manager-dominated firms, whose costly governance practices will make
them increasingly irrelevant to economic activity even within their local jurisdiction.
X. WEAK FORCES FOR CONVERGENCE
We have spoken here of a number of forces pressing toward international
convergence on a relatively uniform standard model of corporate law. Those forces
include the internal logic of efficiency, competition, interest group pressure, imitation, and
the need for compatibility. We have largely ignored two other potential forces that might
also press toward convergence: explicit efforts at cross-boarder harmonization, and
competition between jurisdictions for corporate charters.
A. Harmonization
The European Union has been the locus of the most intense efforts to date at self-
conscious harmonization of corporate law across jurisdictions. That process has,
however, proven a relatively weak force for convergence; where there exists substantial
divergence in corporate law across member states, efforts at harmonization have generally
borne little fruit. Moreover, harmonization proposals have often been characterized by an
effort to impose throughout the EU various forms of regulation whose efficiency is
questionable, with the result that harmonization sometimes seems more an effort to avoid
the standard model than to further it.
33. See generally ROBERTA ROMANO, THE GENIUS OF AMERICAN CORPORATE LAW
(1993).
28
For these reasons, the other pressures toward convergence described above are
likely to be much more important forces for convergence than are explicit efforts at
harmonization. At most, we expect that, once the consensus for adoption of the standard
model has become sufficiently strong, harmonization may serve as a convenient pretext for
overriding the objections of entrenched national interest groups that resist reform of
corporate law within individual states.
B. Competition for Charters
The U.S. experience suggests that cross-border competition for corporate charters
can be a powerful force for convergence in corporate law, and in particular for
convergence on an efficient model.33 It seems quite plausible, however, that the choice of
law rules necessary for this form of competition will not be adopted in most jurisdictions
until substantial convergence has already taken place. We expect that the most important
steps toward convergence can and will be taken with relative rapidity before explicit cross-
border competition for charters is permitted in most of the world, and that the latter process
will ultimately be used, at most, as a means of working out the fine details of convergence
and of ongoing minor experimentation and adjustment thereafter.
XI. LIMITS ON CONVERGENCE
Not all divergence among corporate law regimes reflects inefficiency. Efficient
divergence can arise either through adaptation to local social structures or through fortuity.
Neither logic nor competition are likely to create strong pressure for this form of
divergence to disappear, Consequently, it could survive for a considerable period of time.
Still -- though the rate of change may be slower -- there is good reason to believe that even
the extent of efficient divergence, like the extent of inefficient divergence, will continue to
decrease relatively quickly.
A. Differences in Institutional Context
Sometimes jurisdictions choose alternative forms of corporate law because those
alternatives complement other national differences in, for example, forms of shareholdings,
means for enforcing the law, or related bodies of law such as bankruptcy. A case in point
is the new Russian corporation statute, which deviates self-consciously from the type of
statute that the standard model would call for in more developed economies. To take just
one example, the Russian statute imposes cumulative voting on all corporations as a
mandatory rule, in strong contrast with the corporate law of most developed countries. The
34. Following Russian voucher privatization in 1993, managers and other employees
typically held a majority of shares in large companies. Publicly-held shares were mostly
widely dispersed, but there was often at least one substantial outside shareholder with
sufficient holdings to exploit a cumulative voting rule to obtain board representation. See
Bernard Black and Reinier Kraakman, A Self-Enforcing Model of Corporate Law, 109
HARVARD LAW REVIEW 1911 (1996).
29
reason for this approach was largely to assure some degree of shareholder influence and
access to information in the context of the peculiar pattern of shareholdings that has
become commonplace in Russia as a result of that country’s unique process of mass
privatization.34
Nevertheless, the efficient degree of divergence in corporate law appears much
smaller than the divergence in the other institutions in which corporate activity is
embedded. For example, efficient divergence in creditor protection devices is probably
much narrower than observed differences in the sources and structure of corporate credit.
Similarly, the efficient array of mechanisms for protecting shareholders from managerial
opportunism appears much narrower than the observed variety across jurisdictions in
patterns of shareholdings.
Moreover, the economic institutions and legal structures in which corporate law
must operate are themselves becoming more uniform across jurisdictions. This is
conspicuously true, for example, of patterns of shareholdings. All countries are beginning
to face, or need to face, the same varied types of shareholders, from controlling
blockholders to mutual funds to highly dispersed individual shareholders. Some of this is
driven by the converging forces of internal economic development. Thus, privatization of
enterprise, increases in personal wealth, and the need for start-up finance (which is aided
by a public market that offers an exit for the initial private investors) all promote an
increasing incidence of small shareholdings and a consequent need for strong protection
for minority shareholders. The globalization of capital markets presses to the same end.
Hence Russia, to return to our earlier example, will presumably evolve over time toward the
patterns of shareholdings typical of developed economies, and will ultimately feel the need
to conform its shareholder voting rules more closely to the rules found in those economies.
B. Harmless Mutations
In various cases we anticipate that there will be little or no efficiency difference
among multiple alternative corporate law rules. In these cases, the pressures for
convergence are lessened, although not entirely eliminated (since we still expect global
35. Ronald Gilson refers to processes in which facially different governance structures
or legal rules develop to solve the same underlying functional problem as “functional
convergence.” Ronald J. Gilson, Globalizing Corporate Governance: Convergence of
Form or Function (working paper, 1997). On the assumption that formal law and
governance practices are embedded in larger institutional contexts that change only slowly,
Gilson conjectures that functional convergence is likely to far outpace formal convergence.
Such functional convergence, when it occurs, is what we term harmless mutation. In
contrast to Gilson, however, we believe that formal law and governance structures are less
contextual and more malleable than is often assumed, once the norm of shareholder
primacy is accepted. Functional convergence – rather than straightforward imitation – is
thus less necessary than Gilson supposes. We also suspect that close substitutes among
alternative governance structures and legal rules are less widespread than Gilson implies.
30
investors to exert pressure to standardize).35
Accounting standards offer an example. As we noted earlier, there are currently two
different accounting methodologies that have achieved prominence among developed
nations: the American GAAP and the European-inspired International Accounting
Standards. Because these two sets of standards evolved separately, they differ in many
significant details. From the best current evidence, however, neither obviously dominates
the other in terms of efficiency.
If the economies involved were entirely autarchic, both accounting standards might
well survive indefinitely with no sacrifice in efficiency. The increasing globalization of the
capital markets, however, imposes strong pressure not only for all countries to adopt one
or the other of these regimes, but to select a single common accounting regime. Over
time, then, the network efficiencies of a common standard form in global markets are likely
to eliminate even this and other forms of fortuitous divergence in corporate law.
XII. LIMITS ON THE EFFICIENCY OF CONVERGENCE
Having just recognized that efficiency does not always dictate convergence in
corporate law, we must also recognize that the reverse can be true as well: a high degree
of convergence need not always reflect efficiency. The most likely sources of such
inefficient convergence, we expect, will be flaws in markets or in political institutions that
are widely shared by modern economies, and that are reinforced rather than mitigated by
cross-border competition.
A. Third-party Costs: Corporate Torts
Perhaps the most conspicuous example of inefficient convergence is the rule –
36. See Henry Hansmann and Reinier Kraakman, Toward Unlimited Shareholder
Liability for Corporate Torts, 100 YALE LAW JOURNAL 1879, 1882-83 (1991).
37. By way of contrast, in the U.S. the largely nonstochastic tort of environmental
pollution has made an easier focus for political organizing and, as noted in the text below,
has led to strong legislation that partially pierces the corporate veil for firms that pollute.
31
already universal, with only minor variations from one jurisdiction to the next – that limits
shareholder liability for corporate torts. This rule induces inefficient risk-taking and
excessive levels of risky activities – inefficiencies that appear to outweigh by far any
offsetting benefits, such as reduced costs of litigation or the smoother functioning of the
securities markets. As we have argued elsewhere, a general rule of unlimited pro rata
shareholder liability for corporate torts appears to offer far greater overall efficiencies.36
Why, then, has there been universal convergence on an inefficient rule? The
obvious answer is that neither markets nor politics work well to represent the interests of
the persons who bear the direct costs of the rule, namely tort victims. Since, by definition,
torts involve injuries to third parties, the parties affected by the rule – corporations and their
potential tort victims – cannot contract around the rule to capture and share the gains from
its alteration. At the same time, owing to the highly stochastic nature of most corporate
torts, tort victims – and particularly the very large class of potential tort victims – do not
constitute an easily organized political interest group.37 Moreover, even if a given
jurisdiction were to adopt a rule of shareholder liability for corporate torts, difficulties in
enforcement would arise from the ease with which shareholdings or incorporation can
today be shifted to other jurisdictions that retain the rule of limited liability.
B. Managerialism
A second example of inefficient conversion, arguably, is the considerable freedom
enjoyed by managers in almost all jurisdictions to protect their prerogatives in cases when
they might conflict with those of shareholders, including particularly managers’ ability to
defend their positions against hostile takeover attempts. Again, political and market
failures seem responsible. Dispersed public shareholders, who are the persons most
likely to be disadvantaged by the power of entrenched managers, face potentially serious
problems of collective action in making their voice felt. And managers, whose positions
make them a powerful and influential interest group everywhere, can use their political
influence to keep the costs of collective action high – for example, by making it hard for a
hostile acquirer to purchase an effective control block of shares from current shareholders.
Corporate law might therefore converge, not precisely to the shareholder-oriented
standard model that represents the ideological consensus, but rather to a variant of that
model that has a slight managerialist tilt.
32
C. How Big a Problem?
The problem of inefficient convergence in corporate law appears to be a relatively
limited one, however. Tort victims aside, the relations among virtually all actors directly
affected by the corporation are heavily contractual, which tends to give those actors a
common interest in establishing efficient law. Moreover, as our earlier discussion has
emphasized, shareholders, managers, workers, and voluntary creditors either have or are
acquiring a powerful interest in efficient corporate law. Indeed, limited liability in tort
arguably should not be considered a rule of corporate law at all, but instead should be
viewed as a rule of tort law. And even limited liability in tort may come to be abandoned as
large-scale tort damage becomes more common and consequently of greater political
concern. We already see some movement in this direction in U.S. environmental law,
which pushes aside the corporate veil to a startling degree in particular circumstances.
XIII. CONCLUSION
The triumph of the shareholder-oriented model of the corporation over its principal
competitors is now assured, even if it was problematic as recently as twenty-five years
ago. Logic alone did not establish the superiority of this standard model or of the
prescriptive rules that it implies, which establish a strong corporate management with
duties to serve the interests of shareholders alone, and strong minority shareholder
protections. Rather, the standard model earned its position as the dominant model of the
large corporation the hard way, by out-competing during the post-World-War-II period the
three alternative models of corporate governance: the managerialist model, the labor-
oriented model, and the state-oriented model.
If the failure of the principal alternatives has established the ideological hegemony
of the standard model, however, perhaps this should not come as a complete surprise.
The standard model has never been questioned for the vast majority of corporations. It
dominates the law and governance of closely held corporations in every jurisdiction. Most
German companies do not participate in the co-determination regime, and must Dutch
companies are not regulated by the managerialist “structure” regime. Similarly, the
standard model of shareholder primacy has always been the dominant legal model in the
two jurisdictions where the choice of models might be expected to matter most: the U.S.
and the UK. The choice of models matters in these jurisdictions because large companies
often have highly fragmented ownership structures. In Continental Europe, where most
large companies are controlled, the interests of controlling shareholders traditionally
dominate corporate policy no matter what the prevailing ideology of the corporate form.
We predict, therefore, that as European equity markets develop, the ideological
and competitive attractions of the standard model will become indisputable, even among
legal academics. And as the goal of shareholder primacy becomes second nature even to
33
politicians, convergence in most aspects of the law and practice of corporate governance
is sure to follow.