Statistical and Economic Approaches to Legal History
(Forthcoming in UNIV. OF ILL. L. REV. (2002))
Daniel Klerman
USC Law and Economics & Law and Public Policy
Research Paper No. 02-6
LAW AND ECONOMICS
RESEARCH PAPER SERIES
Sponsored by the John M. Olin Foundation
University of Southern California Law School
Los Angeles, CA 90089-0071
This paper can be downloaded without charge from the Social Science Research Network
electronic library at http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract_id=337500
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
101
STATISTICAL AND ECONOMIC
APPROACHES TO LEGAL HISTORY
Daniel Klerman
*
Professor Klerman advocates increased use of economic and
statistical approaches by legal historians. He documents the dearth of
economic and statistical analysis in legal history and shows how use
of these methods could contribute to the field. Professor Klerman
shows these potential benefits by examining recent articles which use
economics and statistics to explore the determinants and effects of le-
gal change.
This article advances a simple hypothesis: legal history could bene-
fit from more attention to economics and statistics. Legal historians cur-
rently make remarkably little use of economic theory and statistical tests.
Scholars outside the legal history community, most notably economists,
however, have begun to use rational choice theory and regression analy-
sis to investigate issues which are at the core of legal history—the causes
of legal change and the effect of legal change on behavior. Legal history
would be enriched if historians took note of these new methods. Eco-
nomics and statistics cannot, of course, replace the methods currently in
use, but, when used appropriately, they can complement current meth-
ods—each method contributing its own insights and partially compensat-
ing for the weaknesses of the others.
The relative neglect of economics and statistics may reflect misper-
ceptions of these fields, both of which have changed dramatically in the
last two decades. For example, legal historians may reject economic
analysis because they view it as theoretical and abstract, as politically
conservative, or as naively functionalist. While each of these claims
might have been true twenty years ago, they are largely false today. Part
of the goal of this article is to bring to light more recent trends in eco-
nomics which have made it more empirical, less functionalist, less politi-
cally charged, and thus more relevant to legal history.
*
Professor of Law and History, University of Southern California Law School.
The author thanks John de Figueiredo, Charles Donahue, William W. Fischer, Thomas Gallanis,
Ariela Gross, Ron Harris, Dean Lueck, Eric Talley, Thomas Ulen, and Mark Weinstein for their sugges-
tions and criticisms. The author also thanks Jamaul Cannon, Christina Foster, and Steven Rosenfeld for
their excellent research assistance.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
102 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LAW REVIEW [Vol. 2002
This article shares much with a forthcoming article by Ron Harris,
The Encounters of Economic History and Legal History.
1
Harris also ar-
gues that legal historians should pay more attention to economics and
notes recent trends in that discipline that have made it more relevant to
legal history.
2
Harris’s article, however, focuses on the New Historical
Institutional Economics.
3
While I agree that this school has much to of-
fer, this article will focus more on statistical testing than on any single
body of theory.
Part I of this article substantiates the claim that legal historians
make little use of economics and statistics. It does so primarily through
citation analysis of articles and books. Part II attempts to show how eco-
nomics and statistics can contribute to legal history. It provides examples
of recent works that use economics and statistics to illuminate the deter-
minants and effects of legal change. Most of this research was neither
published in legal history journals nor performed by people who would
characterize themselves as legal historians. As a result, it is largely un-
known to the legal history community.
I. ECONOMICS AND STATISTICS IN LEGAL HISTORY
This article starts from the premise that legal historians currently
make little use of economics and statistics. That, of course, is an empiri-
cal assertion that requires substantiation. To that end, consider Table 1.
The first row of the table addresses the use of statistics. Regression
is the most common and most powerful statistical method, so counting
the number of articles and books that use regression is a good way of
measuring the prevalence of statistical analysis.
4
The first two columns
show that only a single article in the most recent legal history journals
used regression analysis.
5
Because the Index to Legal Periodicals covers
law reviews and the gamut of interdisciplinary journals, it sheds light on
legal history articles published outside of specialist journals.
6
Regression
1. Ron Harris, The Encounters of Economic History and Legal History, 21 LAW & HIST. (forth-
coming Summer 2003).
2. Id. at 2, 11–17, 50–54, 59–60 (citations to manuscript version).
3. Id. at 3, 11–33, 52–54 (citations to manuscript version).
4. The simplest statistical tool is a table. Use of tables is, of course, common in legal history.
Nevertheless, because it is difficult to disentangle the effect of several factors or to assess statistical
significance with just a table, I do not consider use of tables to be evidence of serious statistical analy-
sis. Of course, by that criterion, this very article—which has a table but no regressions—would not
qualify as statistical.
5. That article is discussed in Part II.A.2. Of course, there are legal history journals other than
the two in the table, but these are the only two available on-line. In addition, they are the only two
American journals, so they are indicative of the American branch of the discipline. My impression is
that legal historians in other countries are even less likely to use statistical and economic methods.
6. Of course, by looking at articles published in legal history journals, law reviews, and law-
related interdisciplinary journals, I ignore articles of legal history that appeared in history journals.
The neglect of such journals partly reflects the fact that they are not generally accessible in searchable
form. If the exclusion of such journals results in a bias against legal history produced by historians in
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
No. 4] STATISTICS AND ECONOMICS IN LEGAL HISTORY 103
analysis is only slightly more common in these articles.
7
Because books
are a major vehicle for legal-historical writing, it is important to consider
the use of statistics in books as well. The second to last column, how-
ever, indicates that very few legal history books contain regressions. The
last column reports the number of regressions in the Yale Law Journal.
This column provides a useful comparison to mainstream legal scholar-
ship. It indicates that regression analysis is more common there, al-
though still relatively rare.
TABLE 1
REGRESSIONS AND CITATIONS TO ECONOMISTS IN
LEGAL-HISTORICAL WRITING, 1975–2000
American
Journal of
Legal
History
(1994-
1998)
d
Law and
History
Review
(1996-
2001)
e
Articles
classified as
“Legal
History” in
Index to
Legal
Periodicals
(1985-2000)
f
Legal
History
Books
(1975-
2000)
g
Yale
Law
Journal
(1996-
2001)
h
Regressions
a
(performed)
0 1 2 2 4
Gary Becker
b
(citations to)
0 1 2 2 17
Ronald Coase
b
(citations to)
4 7 2 6 34
Robert Fogel
b
(citations to)
2 0 2 9 2
Douglass North
b
(citations to)
0 2 2 8 5
Richard Posner
b
(citations to)
14 14 29 16 92
N
c
464 435 240 332 366
Notes:
a
This row counts the number of articles or books which report the results of at least one regres-
sion performed by the author of the article or book.
b
These rows count the number of articles or books which cite Becker, Coase, Fogel, North, or
Posner.
c
This row records the total number of books or articles (including book reviews) searched.
d
This column was calculated using Westlaw searches. Westlaw coverage of the American Journal
of Legal History began in 1994. The 1999-2001 volumes have not been published yet. This journal is
not on Lexis.
e
This column was calculated using Lexis searches. Lexis has much more complete coverage than
Westlaw for Law and History Review, even though both claim coverage of the same years.
f
The numbers in this column were computed by using Westlaw to compile a list of articles pub-
lished in 1985, 1990, 1995, and 2000 classified as “legal history” by the Index to Legal Periodicals,
downloading those which were available in full text on Westlaw (about two-thirds), and then using
Microsoft’s FindFile Tool to search the downloaded articles.
history departments, I hope that the last column—which examines books reviewed in legal history
journals—at least partially corrects that bias.
7. The figures could be interpreted to mean that statistics are much more common in nonspe-
cialist journals, as regressions appear in almost one percent (2/240) of such articles, whereas they ap-
pear in barely one-tenth of one percent (1/861) of articles appearing in legal history journals. This dif-
ference, however, is mostly due to the fact that the legal history journals include a very large number
of book reviews, which are unlikely to contain regressions, whereas the Index to Legal Periodicals da-
tabase includes relatively few.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
104 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LAW REVIEW [Vol. 2002
g
The numbers in this column were compiled by examining every book reviewed in 1975, 1980,
1990 and 2000 by American Journal of Legal History, Law and History Review, and the Journal of Le-
gal History. The citations counts are based on citations in bibliographies or, if the book had no bibli-
ography, citations in footnotes. Since Law and History did not begin publication until 1983, the table
includes books reviewed in that journal only since 1990. Similarly, since the Journal of Legal History
did not begin publication until 1980, the table includes books reviewed in that journal only since that
year. Since 1998 was the last complete year published by the American Journal of Legal History, that
year was searched instead of the 2000.
h
The numbers in this column were compiled using Westlaw.
The middle rows of the table count the number of articles that cite
leading figures in law and economics and economic history. All but
Richard Posner are Nobel Prize winners. Yet, with the exception of Pos-
ner, they are hardly ever cited in works of legal history. In contrast, lead-
ing law and economics scholars (Becker and Coase) are much more fre-
quently cited in the Yale Law Journal, although that journal cites the
economic historians (Fogel and North) with roughly the same frequency
as the legal history literature. Posner receives a fair number of citations,
in the legal history literature, although significantly fewer than in the
Yale Law Journal. In addition, many of the citations are to the less eco-
nomic parts of his corpus—for example his work on Holmes and Car-
dozo. While the citations to Posner indicate some interest in economics,
the predominance of citations to Posner suggests rather shallow research.
Posner’s works are often the most accessible, but a serious attempt to in-
corporate economic insights would take historians deeper into the litera-
ture.
Although the overall numbers are small, the trend is positive.
There are more regressions and more citations to economists in the most
recent articles and books, even taking into account the increasing num-
ber of legal history publications.
II. ECONOMIC AND STATISTICAL ANALYSIS OF LEGAL HISTORY
Articles applying economics and statistics to legal-historical issues
fall into two broad groups: those that explore the effects of legal change
and those that try to explain legal change. Those in the former category
are usually structured as “event studies,” i.e., attempts to predict and
measure the effects of particular legal changes. Attempts to explain legal
change, the second group, can be subdivided into two primary categories:
functionalist accounts, which see law as generally responding efficiently
to changes in the nonlegal environment, and accounts rooted in public
choice or positive political theory, which explain legal change as the
product of interest groups and institutions.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
No. 4] STATISTICS AND ECONOMICS IN LEGAL HISTORY 105
A. Predicting and Measuring the Effects of Legal Change
Some of the most interesting and successful recent work has used
economic theory and regression analysis to understand the effects of le-
gal rules. In this subsection, I will discuss two examples of this genre.
1. Weinstein’s Work on Limited Liability
Limited corporate liability is generally credited as a hallmark of
modern capitalism and a key institution fostering the sustained economic
growth of the last century and a half. Recent work in economic theory,
however, has undermined this consensus.
8
Because creditors can adjust
interest rates to take into account the greater risks of lending to corpora-
tions with limited liability, the advantages such corporations receive from
greater ease of raising equity capital may be offset by more expensive
debt.
9
In addition, if the benefits of cheaper equity outweighed the cost
of more expensive debt, a corporation could achieve limited liability by
contract. That is, even if the law did not grant corporations limited liabil-
ity, a corporation could negotiate contractual clauses shielding share-
holders from liability. These two considerations suggest that the benefits
of limited liability, if any, would be modest, consisting mostly of reduced
transaction costs, i.e., removing the need to negotiate limited liability in
each debt transaction. Another benefit of limited liability today is shield-
ing shareholders from tort liability. This benefit, however, would have
been small before the mid-twentieth-century expansion of tort liability.
In addition, shielding shareholders from delictual liability is probably in-
efficient, as it encourages managers to take excessive risks.
Although this revisionist theory of corporate liability has attracted
many adherents, many scholars continue to believe that limited liability
remains important and beneficial.
10
Weinstein realized that data from
California provides a way of testing these theories. While nearly all eco-
nomically advanced countries and American states adopted limited li-
ability in the mid-nineteenth-century, before the emergence of modern
equity markets, California changed its corporate law only in the period
1928–31.
11
As a result, it is possible to measure the effect of limited li-
ability by examining the reaction of the stock market to the introduction
8. Paul Halpern et al., An Economic Analysis of Limited Liability in Corporation Law, 30 U.
TORONTO L.J. 117, 147–50 (1980); Henry Hansmann & Reinier Kraakman, Toward Unlimited Share-
holder Liability for Corporate Torts, 100 YALE L.J. 1879, 1932–34 (1991).
9. See Halpern, supra note 8, at 127–29.
10. FRANK H. EASTERBROOK & DANIEL R. FISCHEL, THE ECONOMIC STRUCTURE OF CORPO-
RATE LAW 41–54 (1991); David W. Leebron, Limited Liability, Tort Victims, and Creditors, 91
COLUM. L. REV. 1565 (1991).
11. Mark I. Weinstein, Share Price Changes and the Arrival of Limited Liability in California, 1–
3, 5–7 (Sept. 24, 2001) (unpublished manuscript, on file with the University of Illinois Law Review)
[hereinafter Weinstein, Share Price Changes]; Mark I. Weinstein, Limited Liability in California: 1928–
1931, 2, 16–26 (Aug. 31, 2000) (unpublished manuscript on file with the University of Illinois Law Re-
view) [hereinafter Weinstein, Limited Liability].
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
106 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LAW REVIEW [Vol. 2002
of the new liability regime. If stock prices for California corporations
rose, that would indicate that the benefits of reduced transaction costs
and cheaper equity capital outweighed the cost of more expensive debt.
If the increase was large, it would confirm the importance of limited li-
ability. On the other hand, if stock prices did not rise, that would suggest
that limited liability was not a significant aspect of modern capitalism.
Similar “event studies,” measuring the impact of a wide range of phe-
nomena on stock prices, are common in the finance literature, and their
methodology has been refined over the last few decades.
12
Weinstein applied those methods to California’s adoption of limited
liability.
13
That is, he ran a series of regressions in which the dependent
variable was the stock price of California corporations before and after
the adoption of limited liability, and the explanatory variables were
dummy variables indicating various stages of California’s adoption of
limited liability and a number of control variables.
14
Dummy variables
are variables which take the value of 0 or 1; for example, a key variable
in these regressions was one which was 0 for times before California had
adopted limited liability and 1 afterwards. In such regressions, the coef-
ficients on the dummy variables indicate the effect of the adoption of
limited liability on share prices. The coefficients were small and lacked
statistical significance. So with appropriate caveats taking into account
the small size of his data set, Weinstein concluded that the adoption of
limited liability had no measurable impact on share prices.
15
This finding
lends support to the revisionist view that limited liability is not that im-
portant.
16
2. Klerman’s Work on Private Prosecution
My own work on the private prosecution of crime in thirteenth-
century England provides a very different example of the use of econom-
ics and statistics.
17
For most of the middle ages, criminal prosecutions
could be initiated in two ways: by appeal, which was private prosecution
by the victim or the victim’s family, or by presentment, which was accusa-
tion by a jury. Generations of legal historians had known that appeals
declined during the middle ages, but there was no agreement on when or
why. I first used statistics to ascertain when the number of private prose-
cutions declined.
18
This could not be calculated simply by counting the
12. Eugene F. Fama et al., The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New Information, 10 INT’L ECON.
REV. 1 (1969); G. William Schwert, Using Financial Data to Measure Effects of Financial Regulation,
24 J.L. & ECON. 121 (1981).
13. Weinstein, Share Price Changes, supra note 11; Weinstein, Limited Liability, supra note 11.
14. Weinstein, Share Price Changes, supra note 11, at 6–15.
15. Id. at 9–12, 13–15.
16. Id. at 15–17.
17. Daniel Klerman, Settlement and the Decline of Private Prosecution in Thirteenth-Century
England, 19 L. & HIST. REV. 1 (2001).
18. Id. at 20–35.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
No. 4] STATISTICS AND ECONOMICS IN LEGAL HISTORY 107
number of appeals in the surviving records, because most of the original
documents were lost or damaged. Using regression analysis, however, I
was able to reconstruct the changing rate of appeals. In these regres-
sions, the dependent variable was the number of appeals brought in a
particular year in a particular county and the principle independent vari-
ables were dummy variables for years and counties. In this kind of re-
gression, the coefficients on the year dummy variables measure whether
appeals were common or uncommon in that year. These regressions re-
vealed a much more complex trend in the number of appeals than had
previously been realized, with both a sharp increase in the 1230s and
sharp decreases around 1220 and after 1250.
19
I then used simple economic analysis to try to understand why the
number of appeals changed so dramatically. Private prosecutors were
motivated both by the desire to punish those who harmed them and by a
desire to extract favorable settlements from them. I noticed that judicial
policy towards settlement changed several times during the thirteenth
century. Sometimes settlements were tolerated, while other times they
were disregarded and settling defendants were punished in spite of set-
tlement. I predicted that when settlements were disregarded, potential
prosecutors would have less incentive to bring appeals and that the num-
ber of private prosecutions would be lower. To test this hypothesis, I
constructed a measure of judicial respect for settlement and conducted a
second set of regressions, in which the year dummy variables were re-
placed as independent variables by the measures of respect for settle-
ment. In this set of regressions, positive and significant coefficients on
the variables measuring respect for settlement indicated that the data
were consistent with the hypothesis that changing settlement policy
caused changes in the number of private prosecutions and led to the ul-
timate decline of the appeal.
20
B. Explaining Legal Change
One of the main goals of legal history is to understand and explain
legal change. Economics and statistics can be useful in this task as well.
Work with this goal can be classified into two broad groups: functionalist
and nonfunctionalist. Functionalists tend to assume that the law re-
sponds efficiently to changes in society and thus predict legal change
when economic or social conditions make a different legal rule more ap-
propriate. Nonfunctionalist economic explanations see legal change as
the outcome of negotiation and struggle between interest groups and
governmental officials. Such explanations look to changes in the inter-
ests and strength of various groups as the primary impetus of legal
change.
19. Id. at 26–29.
20. Id. at 40 n.94 and more generally id. at 35–42.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
108 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LAW REVIEW [Vol. 2002
1. Geddes and Lueck: A Functionalist Explanation of Women’s Rights
Geddes and Lueck use property rights analysis to explain the
movement away from coverture.
21
They classify coverture as a regime
where husbands had property rights in their wives’ labor, and they see
statutes that gave women rights to property and earnings as giving them
“self-ownership.”
22
If there were no transaction costs, the Coase Theo-
rem predicts that there would be no difference between these two legal
regimes.
23
Spouses would simply bargain with each other to allocate
work, leisure, and income in optimal ways. Of course, transaction costs
were not zero, because spouses could not make binding contracts with
each other, and, even if they could, it would have been difficult for each
spouse to monitor whether the other was performing his or her part of
the deal. As a result, Geddes and Lueck argue that coverture imposed
real social costs, at least when wages and returns to human capital were
high and when women’s work was hard to monitor.
24
Under these condi-
tions, wives could potentially earn significant amounts by working out-
side the home, especially if they invested in skills and schooling. Never-
theless, coverture gave them little incentive to do so, and husbands’
limited ability to monitor their wives’ work outside the home and their
human capital investments meant that husbands could not force their
wives to exert maximal effort at work or skills acquisition. On the other
hand, if women were given more control over the earnings and property,
they would have economic incentives to work and acquire skills.
25
Using these insights, Geddes and Lueck predicted that states where
wages and schooling were highest would pass laws giving women control
over earnings and property first and that other states would do so as
wages and schooling increased.
26
They then used regression analysis to
test this hypothesis.
27
The data was consistent with their predictions.
Although their analysis was not explicitly functionalist, they implic-
itly assumed that coverture would be abolished when it became particu-
larly costly. That is, they assumed that legislatures responded to eco-
nomic change with legislation that was more appropriate to the new
circumstances.
21. Rick Geddes & Dean Lueck, The Gains from Self-Ownership and the Expansion of Women’s
Rights, __ AM. ECON. REV. __ (2002) (forthcoming).
22. Id. at 2.
23. Id. at 3, 5.
24. Id. at 5–7.
25. Id.
26. Id. at 6, 11–12.
27. Id. at 12–17.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
No. 4] STATISTICS AND ECONOMICS IN LEGAL HISTORY 109
2. de Figueiredo and Tiller: A Nonfunctionalist Explanation of the
Judicial Expansion
In recent years, functionalist explanations have been heavily criti-
cized as naively assuming that law responds efficiently to social change
and neglecting the complexities of the political process.
28
Recent work in
economics reflects a move away from functionalism towards public
choice and positive political theory. These theories model political deci-
sions, including legislation, as the product of the interplay of interests
and institutions. Depending on the constellation of interests and institu-
tions, social changes may not be reflected in legislation, and inefficient
legislation may be passed.
de Figueiredo and Tiller’s work on the expansion of the judiciary is
emblematic of this new approach.
29
In their view, legislation increasing
the number of federal judgeships could be motivated either by “institu-
tional efficiency” (the public interest) or “political efficiency” (partisan
advantage). The institutional efficiency rationale suggests that legislators
would create new judgeships when increased judicial caseloads indicate
that there was a need for more judges.
30
If motivated by political effi-
ciency, legislators would expand the judiciary when they were confident
that the judges who would fill the new judgeships would share Congress’s
political ideology. On the latter view, legislation authorizing judicial ex-
pansion should be more likely when one party controls the House, Sen-
ate, and Presidency, and when that party will continue to control the
Senate and Presidency long enough to nominate and confirm the judges.
Only when there is political alignment of this kind can those who pass
the legislation reasonably believe that the new judges will share the poli-
ticians’ policy preferences.
31
de Figueiredo and Tiller tested the relative strength of the institu-
tional and political efficiency rationales by examining all legislation to
expand the federal courts of appeals passed between 1869 and 1991.
During that period, twenty-five Congresses enacted legislation to expand
the appellate judiciary. In twenty-one of those Congresses, the House
and Senate were controlled by the same party as the Presidency.
32
While
this simple statistic provides persuasive confirmation for the political ef-
ficiency theory, the authors also use regression analysis, which allows
them to test the relative strength of the partisan and public interest theo-
ries. In their first regression, the dependent variable was a dummy vari-
28. See DOUGLASS NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND ECONOMIC PER-
FORMANCE, 131–40 (1990); Robert W. Gordon, Critical Legal Histories, 36 STAN. L. REV. 57, 100–01
(1984).
29. John M. de Figueiredo & Emerson Tiller, Congressional Control of the Courts: A Theoretical
and Empirical Analysis of Expansion of the Federal Judiciary, 39 J.L. & ECON. 435 (1996).
30. Id. at 438–39.
31. Id. at 444–45.
32. Id. at 447.
KLERMAN.DOC 4/11/2002 4:44 PM
110 UNIVERSITY OF ILLINOIS LAW REVIEW [Vol. 2002
able which was 1 if a particular Congress enacted legislation to expand
the judiciary, and 0 if it did not. The most important dependent variables
were the caseload per appellate judge and a dummy variable that was 1 if
the House, Senate, and Presidency were controlled by the same party as
the nominating President and confirming Senate, and 0 if not. There was
no statistically significant relationship between caseloads and the expan-
sion of the judiciary, but expansion was more than fifty-percent more
likely when the House, Senate, and Presidency were in political align-
ment. The data are thus more consistent with the political efficiency ra-
tionale than with the institutional efficiency, public interest theory.
33
In addition to analyzing the timing of the expansion of the judiciary,
Tiller and de Figueiredo examined the number of new judgeships cre-
ated. To do so, they used a regression similar to that described above,
except that the dependent variable was the number of judgeships cre-
ated. In this regression, both caseload and partisan alignment independ-
ent variables were statistically significant. This suggests that, when Con-
gress has decided to expand the judiciary, the size of the expansion is
determined both by the public interest and by partisan advantage.
34
III. CONCLUSION
It is hoped that the analysis in this article has convinced at least a
few legal historians that there is room in the field for more economics
and statistics. The four studies discussed here indicate, I believe, that
economics and statistics can be employed usefully to investigate a wide
range of legal-historical issues, from the decline of private criminal
prosecutions in the middle ages to the emergence of women’s rights in
the nineteenth century. While it is possible to argue with many of the
premises and conclusions employed in these articles, I think they demon-
strate the utility and power of techniques that are currently neglected by
most legal historians.
33. Id. at 447–53.
34. Id. at 453–59.