R ESEARCH PAPER S ERIES
RESEARCH PAPER NO. 1808
Competing For The Public
Through The News Media
David P. Baron
June 2003
Research Paper No. 1808
COMPETING FOR THE PUBLIC
THROUGH THE NEWS MEDIA
David P. Baron
Stanford University
June 2003
Abstract
Interest groups seek to influence economic activity through public and private
politics. Public politics takes place in the arenas of public institutions, whereas
private politics takes place outside public institutions often in the arena of public
sentiment. Private politics refers to action by interest groups directed at private
parties, as in the case of an activist group launching a campaign against a firm.
This paper presents a model of informational competition between an activist and
an industry, where each interest group seeks to influence public sentiment and does
so by advocating its position through the news media. Citizen consumers make
both a private consumption decision and a collective choice on the regulation of
a product that has an externality associated with it. In the absence of the news
organization the collective choice in not to regulate. The activist and the industry
obtain private, hard information on the seriousness of the externality and advocate
favorable information and may conceal unfavorable information. The news media
can conduct investigative journalism to obtain its own information and based on
that information and the information it has received from its sources, provides a
news report to the public. Due to its role in society, the media has an incentive
tobiasitsreport,andthedirectionofbiasistowardregulation.Itsbiasservesto
mitigate both the market failure by decreasing demand and a government failure
by leading to regulation. The activist then has an incentive to conceal information
unfavorable to its interests, whereas the industry fully reveals its information.
Competing for the Public Through the News Media
1
David P. Baron
Stanford University
I. Introduction
Interest groups seek to influence economic activity through public and private politics.
Public politics takes place in the arenas of public institutions, whereas private politics takes
place outside public institutions often in the arena of public sentiment. Public politics fo-
cuses on government policy, such as regulation and tax and expenditure policy. Private
politics refers to action by interest groups directed at private parties, as in the case of
an activist group launching a campaign against a firm. This can be independent of gov-
ernment but generally draws strength from the public, as in the case of a boycott. This
paper presents a model in which interest groups compete for public sentiment through the
news media to influence the public politics of regulation and private politics through the
consumption decisions of citizens. In addition, the paper provides an explanation of media
bias in terms of the role of the news media in society.
In private politics activist strategies often focus on pressuring firms through the mem-
bers of the public both in their roles as consumers and their roles as constituents of public
officeholders. In response, opposing interest groups may counteract those strategies through
both private and public political strategies. For example, the strategic competition between
activists and firms frequently focuses on public sentiment about the activities of the firm.
The instrument of that competition is advocacy—communicating information to the public
favorable to the interest group’s objectives while remaining silent about information un-
favorable to those objectives. This communication can be direct to the public, but it can
be more efficient to communicate through the news media, which can be a low-cost means
of communicating with the public. In his study of 24 ecological boycotts led by activists
Friedman (1999, Ch. 8) found that 22 were directed at the news media. Since interest
groups direct their communication strategies to it, the news media has a role in private
politics (Baron (2002)(2003b)). The news media can be viewed as a private institution in
1
This research was supported by NSF Grant No. SES-0111729. I would like to thank
Bharat Anand, Larry Bartels, and seminar participants at Columbia University, Harvard
University, and Princeton University for their comments.
1
whose arena interest groups compete to influence public and private politics. In the 1950s
and 1960s this role led commentators to refer to the news media as the fourth branch of
government or the “fourth estate.”
The news media provides information to the members of the public for their private
and collective decisions, and in doing so it has considerable discretion in determining what
information is reported. Moreover, it may have its own objectives based on self-interest
as well as on principles of journalism as embodied in the profession. The media thus can
have a strategic role in influencing public sentiment and hence the outcomes of private and
public politics. The media’s reporting also can affect the strategies of its sources, and it
may conduct investigative journalism to uncover the concealment of information.
The strategic competition considered here is between interest groups, an activist and
an industry, and pertains to an externality associated with the consumption of a product.
The competition takes the form of communicating information about the seriousness of the
externality to the public through the news media. The news media exercises discretion on
what it reports to the public, and based on that report, the members of the public individu-
ally decide whether to consume the product and collectively decide whether to regulate the
externality. The media’s reporting strategy thus can affect both private and public politics,
and in equilibrium the media biases its news report to mitigate both a government failure
and a market failure. Bias in this case can serve the interests of the public, even though
individuals are fully rational and skeptical of the news report. In addition to providing
information, the news media may be able to make normative arguments regarding the ex-
ternality with the objective of changing the public’s preferences. The change in behavior
resulting from such moral suasion can be a substitute for regulation.
II. An Example of an Issue and the Competition
The issue of corporate average fuel economy (CAFE) standards for light vehicles pro-
vides an example of a competition between activists and firms with the news media provid-
ing information to the public for their private and collective decisions. The CAFE standard
for passenger cars has remained at 27.5 mpg since 1985, and the standard for light trucks,
which includes SUVs, has remained at 20.7 mpg since a small increase in 1996. Environ-
mental activists and their allies in Congress have sought to increase the standard. The
2
Sierra Club has worked for a standard of 40 mpg for automobiles to be achieved over 10
years. Since SUVs and light trucks represent nearly 50 percent of the market, Senators
John Kerry and John McCain sought to replace the two standards with a single standard
of35mpgtobeachievedover12years.
A principal component of the strategy of the environmental groups has been to em-
phasize the seriousness of the global climate change issue and recently to add the national
security issue of the reliance on imported oil. In public politics environmentalists sought
to increase constituent pressure on representatives. The automakers countered by empha-
sizing the revealed preferences of consumers for larger and more powerful vehicles and the
additional injuries and fatalities that would result from downsizing vehicles to meet sharply
higher fuel economy standards. The status quo was advantaged in public politics, and the
legislative efforts failed in 2002.
After failing to achieve higher CAFE standards in Congress, the Sierra Club turned to
private politics. It sought to mobilize the public against the automakers’ refusal to improve
the fuel economy of their vehicles. The Sierra Club began a three-year campaign to put
public pressure directly on the big-three automakers. As Carl Pope, executive director
of the Sierra Club, explained “we’re going now to the customers.” The Sierra Club hired
Haddow Communications to conduct an advertising campaign challenging the automobile
companies.
2
The radio ads specifically called on CEO Bill Ford, “Now more than ever,
America needs cars that get better gas mileage. That’s why we’re asking Bill Ford, head
of the Ford Motor Company, to do his part and to produce more fuel efficient, SUV’s and
pickup trucks.”
Separately, another group aired television commercials arguing that buying an SUV
supported terrorism and threatened national security by increasing the dependence on
imported oil. News coverage of the activist campaigns increased the attention given to the
issues. As The New York Times observed, “the message is attracting attention through
2
Television spots featured former Nebraska senator Bob Kerrey and retired Navy vice
admiral Jack Shanahan. In one ad Kerrey said, “Its time for us to tell the auto industry
that we want to break the grip of oil-producing countries and reduce our oil use.” In another
Kerrey stated, “We ask our young men and women to sacrifice their safety and perhaps
their lives to fight the war against terrorism. We all know that our dependency on imported
oil is part of the problem and we know that increasing the fuel economy of the cars we
driveispartofthesolution.”
3
news coverage.”
3
TheSierraClubobtainedleveragethroughmediacoverageof thecampaignandthrough
a variety of actions intended to emphasize recent decreases in fleet fuel economy and the
seriousness of the global climate change issue. The news media regularly reported on fuel
economy data and regulation, and the activists and the industry provided information to
influence those reports. For example, environmental activists railed against the introduc-
tion of the Hummer H2, which was sufficiently heavy that it was not subject to any fuel
economy standards. Earlier, the Sierra Club had campaigned against the Ford Excursion,
which it dubbed the Ford Valdez. Ford decided to drop the Excursion.
In 2003 the Bush administration increased the light truck standard to 22.2 mpg by
model year 2007. The administration argued that the increase would save 2.5 billion gallons
of gasoline, but critics claimed that the automobile industry was already planning increases
greater than in the new standard. Daniel Becker of the Sierra Club called the action by the
Bush administration “irresponsible.” The big three automakers criticized the new standard
as costing more than it was worth and costing the nation badly needed jobs.
III. Overview
A. Literature on the News Media
The impact of the news media on public politics is broadly observable (Graber (2000)).
For example, following the oil crises in the 1970s Erfle and McMillan (1990) found that
media coverage affected the price of home heating oil relative to the price of bunker oil sold
to electric utilities. They concluded that oil companies restrained their price increases to
forestall a public reaction and possible new regulation. Stromberg (2001) has shown that as
the U.S. radio audience increased in the 1930s more relief funds were allocated to counties
with more listeners.
Besley and Burgess (2002), Besley and Prat (2001), and Besley, Burgess, and Pratt
(2002) studied models of political agency focusing on the relation between an incumbent
officeholder and an electorate that obtained information from the news media. Besley and
Burgess considered a model in which the media provides information about government
performance to the electorate, and this induces the government to be responsive to the
3
The New York Times, January 8, 2003.
4
interests of the public. They test the model using data from India and find that state
governments are more responsive to the public’s needs the broader is newspaper readership.
Besley and Pratt focused on the opportunity for the government to capture the media and
found that inefficiency and malfeasance can result. In their model the government is a
source of information for the media and hence may manipulate that information. In the
model considered here the sources of information are interest groups.
Stromberg (2002) presented a model in which increasing returns to scale and adver-
tising incentives drive the media to provide more information to large and higher income
groups than to smaller and lower income groups. These incentives for media bias can affect
public policy. Media bias can also arise from within the news organization.
4
The American
Association of Newspaper Editors (1999) (www.asne.org/index.cfm?d=2632) conducted a
survey and concluded, “The public suspects that the points of view and biases of journalists
influence what stories are covered and how they are covered.” Although the public broadly
views the news media as biased, individuals differ considerably in their perception of the
nature and direction of that bias.
Bovitz, Druckman, and Lupia (2002) used a hierarchical model of a news organization
to explain the sources of bias and the forces that act to control it. The sources of bias are
the ideological orientations of media elites, but for those orientations to influence public
opinion, editors must either accept an ideologically-biased report by a journalist or bias a
report to serve the ideological orientation of the owners of the media organization. Bias
can be mitigated by the career concerns of editors and by the audience. The audience must
be willing to read the report, and for it to have influence the media must bias information
in a direction contrary to the initial beliefs of the audience.
Mullainathan and Shleifer (2002) provide a model in which bias can arise both from
an ideological orientation of the news organization and from incentives to tell an interest-
ing story. The ideological bias arises from the preferences of journalists, and the bias in
their stories can be neutralized if there is an ideological balance among competing news
organizations. The incentives to tell an interesting story come from a preference to be well
4
Attention has also been given to the effect of media competition on programming
(Spence and Owen (1977), Owen and Wildman (1992), Noam (1985)(1987)) and to the wel-
fare analysis of media competition (Anderson and Coate (2001), Hansen and Kyhl (2001),
Dukes and Gal-Or (2001)).
5
thought of by readers, and in a psychology-based model of the audience these incentives can
produce bias. In the model considered here bias results from the assumed responsibilities of
the media to serve the public, in this case by mitigating a market failure and a government
failure.
A number of cross-country studies have been conducted on the influence of the media
on politics and the economic performance of countries. In the realm of private politics
Dyck and Zingales (2002) consider the effect of the news media on the behavior of corpo-
rate executives and directors in choosing “socially responsible” corporate activities. They
conclude that the media has substantial impact on the environmental policies of firms and
on governance. In the model presented here the news media influences the public in both
their consumption decisions and in their collective choice on regulation.
Hamilton (1996) argued that television programming exhibits market failures in edu-
cational programming for children, public affairs coverage, and indecent and violent pro-
gramming. The market failures result in an oversupply of programming with negative
externalities and an undersupply of programming with positive externalities. He argued
for regulation to correct the market failures. In the model presented here the media acts
in response to a market failure arising not from within the media market but among the
public.
B. Overview of the Model
The model focuses on the competition between activists and firms and the role of the
news media in that competition. The model describes how the media informs the public
based on information provided by an activist, firms, and possibly its own investigative
journalism. The model provides an explanation of media bias as a function of media
preferences and the opportunity to influence the public. It also provides an explanation
for the communication strategies of the activist and the firms. Ultimately, a theory should
identify the role of the news media in interest group competition as a private institution
with “officeholders” who self-select into the profession of journalism. The current model
provides a first step in that direction.
At the center of the competition between the activist and the firms are a private
consumption decision of citizen consumers and a collective choice to regulate the product
they consume. The private decision pertains to a product that has associated with it an
6
unregulated externality. The collective choice is whether to regulate the externality, where
the form of regulation is a product standard. The private decisions of citizen consumers
may be thought of as whether to purchase a low fuel economy vehicle, and the public
decision may be thought of as whether to impose a CAFE standard.
Citizenconsumershaveincompleteinformationabouttheseriousness of theexternality,
and the news media provides a soft report on the seriousness based on information from
its sources and its own investigative journalism. Citizen consumers are rational and take
into account the possible bias in the report from either the news media or its sources. The
sources are an activist, whose interests are in dampening the demand for the product and
regulating the externality, and firms that produce the product and oppose regulation.
The activist and the firms are better informed than is the media, and they act strate-
gically to influence the media’s news report. Their influence takes the form of advocacy,
where they communicate favorable (hard) information to the media and may conceal un-
favorable information. The media may investigate the seriousness of the externality if it
does not receive hard information from the activist or the firms. Investigative journalism
both informs the media and provides an opportunity to expose possible concealment by its
sources. If concealment is exposed, the activist or the firms suffer reputation damage.
The firms are assumed to compete in the market but to act collectively as an industry
in dealing with the activist, the media, and the public.
5
Citizen consumers are sophisticated
and anticipate the strategies of the activist, firms, and media. They subscribe to the media’s
service only if they expect to benefit from it, and those who do not subscribe benefit from
an informational spillover.
The preferences of the activist are to mitigate the externality, and the firms maximize
their profits. The objectives of the news media are a combination of profits, journalistic
responsibilities, and journalistic performance. The responsibilities pertain to its role in
society to serve the public by providing information to citizen consumers to improve their
private and collective choices. Journalistic performance pertains to exposing concealment
by sources, which can enhance the media’s reputation.
The model focuses on the case in which the media can influence the collective decision.
5
Collective action by firms in public politics is allowed under the Noerr Pennington
doctrine based on the right to free speech.
7
That is, in the absence of the media the collective choice is not to regulate, but if the
media’s report indicates that the externality is very serious, the collective choice is to regu-
late. Because of its responsibility to serve citizen consumers in their private and collective
choices, the news media may have an incentive to bias its report in the direction of greater
seriousness of the issue when there is a collective choice failure and thus lead citizens to
regulate the externality. The news media has an opportunity to bias its report only when
it does not have hard information, either from its sources or its own investigation. Figure
1 illustrates the model and identifies the influences on private and public politics.
The news media also might be able to affect the private decisions of citizen consumers
by causing them to take the externality into account in their consumption decisions. This
moral suasion can be a substitute for regulation.
C. Results
Demand for the firms’ product and industry profit are decreasing in citizen consumers’
beliefs about the seriousness of the externality and the extent to which they internalize
the externality associated with their purchases. The support for regulation is decreasing in
consumers’ valuation for the product, since regulation reduces the value of the product. The
number of citizens who prefer regulation is increasing in the seriousness of the externality
but is decreasing in the extent to which consumers internalize the externality. The news
report thus can directly affect the private decisions of consumers and the industry as well
as the collective choice on regulating the externality.
The activist and the industry may provide hard information to the media, and their
communication strategies take the form of advocacy, where the sources present favorable
information and may conceal unfavorable information. The media’s beliefs that the exter-
nality is serious are increasing in the probability that the industry conceals unfavorable
information and decreasing in the probability that the activist conceals unfavorable infor-
mation. These properties carry over to the public’s beliefs given a news report that the
externality is serious.
The media reports hard information when it has it, but when it has no hard informa-
tion, it can bias its report. The incentive for bias is due to preferences that depend on the
aggregate welfare of the public, whereas the collective choice is determined by the pivotal
voter. This incentive is only present when the media can influence the collective choice, so
8
bias is both instrumental and opportunistic. In that case, the media biases its report in
favor of regulation to mitigate both a market failure represented by the externality and a
government failure due to a (super)majority requirement. Media bias thus can be welfare
enhancing.
The media’s bias provides incentives for concealment by its sources, but in equilibrium
it is only the activist that conceals information. Concealment by the activist increases the
opportunity for the media to bias its report in favor of regulation. Bias thus induces an
alignment of interests between the news media and the activist; i.e., with the party whose
interests are favored by the bias. Concealment and bias are thus synergistic. When it biases
its report, the media need not fear being exposed because the interest group that could
expose it has preferences for regulation that are aligned with those of the media. Because
the bias is only in one direction, the public believes a report that the issue is not serious
and is skeptical of a report that it is serious. The public becomes more skeptical of the
media’s report the more likely is the activist to conceal unfavorable information.
Since the news media biases its report against the interests of the industry, the industry
has no incentive to conceal unfavorable information. The activist, however, conceals with
positive probability, and that probability is limited only by the risk of being exposed for
having concealed information. The activist may conceal unfavorable information with prob-
ability one if the damage to its reputation from being exposed is small. The informational
competition between the activist and the industry is thus one-sided.
The media is assumed to conduct investigative journalism only if it receives no hard
information from its sources. Investigative journalism is costly, and the incentive to bear
the cost comes from the possibility of both becoming better informed and enhancing its
reputation by exposing concealment by one of its sources.
If it could conceal the hard information from its sources or its investigative journalism,
the media will do so only in the same event in which the activist has an incentive to
conceal its hard information. The equilibrium for the case in which the media can conceal
information is thus qualitatively the same as when it cannot conceal hard information.
Moral suasion by the news media reduces the harm from the externality and decreases
the public support for regulation. Moral suasion is thus a substitute for regulation and
for biased media reports. Moral suasion may eliminate the media’s informational influence
9
andhenceitsincentivestobiasitsnewsreport.
In the model the bias of the news media is due not to the personal preferences of those
in the news organization but is instead due to the objective of serving the interest of the
public.
6
That is, the media provides information about a market failure and a collective
choice that benefits the public as a whole but is not preferred by a sufficient majority to
overcome the status quo advantage in pivotal politics. This comes at the expense of truthful
reporting.
IV. Time Line and Information Structure
Figure 2 identifies the sequence of actions in the game. In the information stage the ac-
tivist and the firms search for information about the issue, and in the communication stage
they send messages to the news media. The media then sets a price for a subscription, and
citizen consumers who expect to benefit subscribe to the media reports. The media decides
whether to conduct investigative journalism, and if it does, it searches for information.
The media then provides a report. Citizen consumers next collectively choose whether to
regulate the product, and given that decision, the firms set prices for their products, and
citizen consumers make their consumption decisions.
A state of nature θ cantakeontwovaluesθ ∈{θ
L
,θ
H
}, θ
L
<θ
H
,andthecommon
knowledge prior probability is p = Pr(θ = θ
H
). The interpretation is, for example, that θ
H
corresponds to global climate change being very serious, whereas θ
L
means it is not serious.
The state θ
H
is favorable to the activist’s cause of dampening demand and obtaining
regulation of the externality, and the state θ
L
is favorable to the interests of the firms.
In the information stage the activist and the firms search simultaneously for informa-
tion about the state, and each search is successful with probability q ∈ (0,1) and unsuccess-
ful with probability 1 ? q. For the news media, investigative journalism is successful with
probability q
M
. A successful search provides hard information that is conclusive evidence
that the state is θ
H
or θ
L
, and an unsuccessful search yields no information, which will be
denoted by φ. The cost to the public of verifying hard information is assumed to be high,
6
Journalists may also have individual preferences that influence news stories. Pat-
terson and Donsbach (1996), for example, surveyed journalists in five countries and con-
cluded “there is a significant correlation between journalists’ personal beliefs and their news
decisions.”
10
so the activist and the firms cannot communicate their information directly to the public.
The public relies on the soft report by the news media. The activist and the firms thus
communicate to the public through the news media. The news media is assumed to be able
to evaluate the information provided by the activist and the firms, so the sources cannot
fake information.
The rest of the model is introduced in the following sections beginning at the end of
the game. Because of the complexity of the strategic situation the model is formulated in
a relatively simple form.
V. The Public
A. The Public as Citizen Consumers
Each member of the public makes a private decision whether to purchase the product,
e.g., a low fuel economy vehicle, and collectively the public chooses whether to regulate the
product, e.g., impose a fuel economy standard. Citizens differ only in their valuation v for
the product, and the public is assumed to consist of N citizens with valuations distributed
uniformly on the interval [0,?v]. That is, the distribution is Nf(v)wheref(v)=
1
?v
,v∈ [0,?v].
Purchasing a low fuel economy vehicle generates one unit of emissions, which is assumed
to be a pure public bad that costs each citizen θ. Regulation in the form of a standard
s ∈ (0,1) can be imposed to reduce the emissions proportionately to (1 ? s)θ.Regulation
also affects the value of the product. The valuation with regulation is assumed to be given
by v(1?αs), where α ∈ [0,
1
s
)isaparameter.
7
The automakers argue that α>1, reflecting
downsizing, reductions in power, and reduced safety.
An indication that α>1wasgivenincongressionaltestimonybyEdwardB.Cohen,vice
president of Honda North America.
8
He stated, “If the current car fleet were still at 1981
performance, weight and transmission levels, the passenger car CAFE would be almost
36 mpg instead of the current level of 28.1 mpg. The trend is particularly pronounced
since 1987. Based on EPA’s data, technology has gone into the fleet from 1987 to 2000
at a rate that could have increased fuel economy by about 1.5% per year, if it had not
7
The specifications (1?s)θ fortheemissionsand(1?αs)v for the valuation are to be
understood as local rather than global properties of regulation.
8
Honda is the only automobile company operating in the United States that is not a
member of the Alliance of Automobile Manufacturers and the only one not opposing a
substantial increase in fuel economy standards. Honda has the highest fleet fuel economy.
11
instead focused on other vehicle attributes demanded by the market. There is no reason
why this technology trend of improved efficiency (as opposed to fuel economy) should not
continue.”
9
He indicated that average vehicle weight had increased by 12% from 1987 to
2000 and average horsepower increased by 70%. This testimony implies that the auto
industry has responded to consumer demand by using improved fuel efficiency to provide
increases in vehicle size and power, resulting in no improvement in fuel economy. This
suggests that higher fuel economy standards would have substantially reduced the value of
the vehicles to consumers. The analysis thus focuses on the case of α≥1.
B. Private Choice
Citizen v’s expected utility u
v
from consumption is specified as
u
v
= z
v
(v(1? αs
+
)?y ?(1? s
+
)θ
+
ηN),
where y is the price of the product, θ
+
denotes the mean of v’sposteriorbeliefsaboutθ given
the media’s news report, s
+
∈{0,s} is the standard corresponding to θ
+
,andz
v
∈{0,1} is
an indicator variable with z
v
= 1 denoting a purchase and z
v
= 0 denoting no purchase.
10
The cost to citizen v of the externality from her purchase is (1 ? s
+
)θ
+
,andη ∈ [
1
N
,1]
denotes the extent to which the citizen takes into account the effect of her purchase on
others. Thus, η =
1
N
corresponds to ignoring those effects, and η =1correspondstotaking
them fully into account. The parameter η is thus a measure of other-regardedness. A
free-rider problem is present when η<1. The parameter η is a characteristic of preferences
and is independent of information about the seriousness of the issue. Initially, η is treated
as fixed and small, and in Section X it is viewed as responsive to moral suasion.
A citizen with a valuation v satisfying
v ≥ v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
,y) ≡
y +(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN
1?αs
+
purchases the product, and the others do not. The demand X(s
+
,θ
+
,y) for the product is
then
X(s
+
,θ
+
,y)=N
parenleftBig
1?
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
,y)
?v
parenrightBig
. (1)
9
Statement of Edward B. Cohen, vice president, Honda North America, before the
Senate Committee on Commerce, Science and Transportation, December 6, 2001.
10
To simplify the model, s
+
is assumed to be either 0 or s.Thatis,s is the standard
when the media reports that the externality is very serious, and otherwise the standard is
0.
12
The price is established by Cournot competition conditional on θ
+
and s
+
.Eachof
the n firms in the industry is assumed to be identical, and to simplify the model each is
assumed to have zero cost. The profit pi
i
of firm i then is
pi
i
= P(X)x
i
,
where x
i
is the output of firm i, X =Σ
n
i=1
x
i
, P(X) is the inverse demand function obtained
from X(s
+
,θ
+
,y)andv
?
(s
+
,θ
+
,y). The equilibrium price y
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)is
y
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)=
1
n +1
parenleftBig
?v(1?αs
+
)?(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN
parenrightBig
, (2)
so the price reveals the information the firms have. From (1) information that the ex-
ternality is more serious (higher θ
+
) reduces demand, and the firms respond with lower
prices. Despite the lower price, demand is lower the higher is θ
+
. The marginal valuation
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
) ≡ v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
,y
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)) is
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)=
?v
n +1
+
n(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN
(n +1)(1?αs
+
)
, (3)
which is strictly increasing in θ
+
and in s
+
for α>1, so regulation decreases the demand
for the product. Demand X(s
+
,θ
+
) ≡ X(s
+
,θ
+
,y
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)) is
X(s
+
,θ
+
)=
n
n +1
N
(1?αs
+
)?v
parenleftBig
?v(1?αs
+
)?(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN
parenrightBig
, (4)
which is positive if ?v>
(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN
(1?αs
+
)
, which will be assumed to be the case when η is small.
11
That is, there is some consumer who purchases. The externality θ
+
X(s
+
,θ
+
), however,
could exceed ?v; i.e., the externality could be quite serious.
The profit pi
?
i
(s
+
,θ
+
)offirmi is
pi
?
i
(s
+
,θ
+
)=
Ny
?
(θ
+
)
2
(1?αs
+
)?v
=
N(?v(1?αs
+
)?(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN)
2
(n +1)
2
(1?αs
+
)?v
.
(5)
The price in (2) is decreasing in θ
+
, η, α, s
+
,andn and increasing in ?v. Similarly, the
profitisdecreasinginθ
+
, s
+
for α>1, the competitiveness (n) of the industry, and the
extent (η) to which consumers internalize the externality.
12
11
The proportion of consumers who purchase is increasing in ?v and lim
?v→∞
v
?
?v
=
1
n+1
.
12
Profit is decreasing in the standard only if α>1. The increases in CAFE standards
during the 1970s and 1980s shifted considerable market share and profits from the big
three automakers to the producers of smaller, higher fuel economy vehicles.
13
All citizens with valuations at least v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
) purchase the product, so the externality
is (1 ? s
+
)θ
+
X(s
+
,θ
+
)=(1? s
+
)θ
+
N(1 ?
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)
?v
). Regulation directly reduces the
emissions and also reduces demand which further reduces emissions. The externality is
stronger the more competitive is the industry and weaker the more consumers internalize
it.
Since the externality is a pure public bad, every citizen incurs the harm. Consequently,
the utility U
1
(s
+
,θ
+
;v) of a citizen with v≥v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)is
U
1
(s
+
,θ
+
;v)=v(1?αs
+
)?y
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)?(1?s
+
)θ
+
X(s
+
,θ
+
)?(1?s
+
)θ
+
(ηN ?1)
=(1?αs
+
)
parenleftBig
v?
?v
n +1
parenrightBig
+
1
n +1
(1?s
+
)θ
+
ηN ?(1?s
+
)θ
+
(ηN ?1)
?
parenleftBig
1?
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)
?v
parenrightBig
(1?s
+
)θ
+
N.
(6)
The utility U
0
(s
+
,θ
+
;v) of a citizen who does not purchase is
U
0
(s
+
,θ
+
;v)=?(1?s
+
)θ
+
X(s
+
,θ
+
). (7)
The news media has an opportunity through the report it presents about θ to affect
both private and public politics. Private politics pertains to the consumption decisions
of citizens, and public politics corresponds to the collective choice of the regulation. One
influence of the news media on private politics is to affect demand for the product. As
considered in Section X, the media might also be able to affect demand through moral
suasion. The influence on public politics is through the portion of the public that supports
regulation.
C. Collective Choice
Public politics governs the choice of the regulation, where the status quo is no regula-
tion (s
+
= 0). Pivotal politics theory (Krehbiel (1998)(1999)) predicts that a change in the
status quo can require a supermajority to overcome a filibuster in the Senate or override a
presidential veto. A supermajority may also be required to overcome vote buying (Grose-
close and Snyder (1996)). The relation between citizen preferences and the supermajority
required to change the status quo is not known, however, so instead of modeling the in-
stitutions, the supermajority γ of the public required for regulation to be enacted will be
taken as a parameter where γ≥
1
2
. Each citizen is assumed to act as if she is pivotal.
14
A citizen who does not purchase the product prefers regulation because she only bears
the harm from the emissions, as indicated in (7). The valuation v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) of the citizen
who purchases and is indifferent between s
+
= s and no regulation is, using (6), defined by
U
1
(0,θ
+
;v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
))?U
1
(s
+
,θ
+
;v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) ≡ 0.
Solving for v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) yields
v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
)=
?v
n +1
+
θ
+
N
(n +1)α?v(1 ? αs
+
)
parenleftBigparenleftBig
n? η +(n +1)
parenleftBig
η ?
1
N
parenrightBigparenrightBig
?v(1 ? αs
+
)
?(2?α? s
+
)nθ
+
ηN
parenrightBig
.
(8)
Appendix A presents conditions such that v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
)<?v and v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
)>v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
), and
these conditions will be assumed to be satisfied. Since U
1
(·)isincreasinginv, all citizens
with v>v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) oppose regulation. The support for regulation is decreasing in the com-
petitiveness of the industry and is increasing in the number N of citizens affected by the
externality. The support for regulation is decreasing in ?v,andlim
?v→∞
v
o
?v
=
1
n+1
.
The valuation v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) of the citizen who is indifferent between regulation and no
regulation is increasing in s for α>1, so a higher standard receives less support from among
the purchasers of the product. The valuation v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) of the indifferent citizen is increas-
ing in θ
+
when
?v >
2(2?α?s
+
)nθ
+
ηN
(n?η +(n +1)(η?
1
N
))(1?αs
+
)
, (9)
in which case support for regulation increases as the externality becomes more severe. This
condition is satisfied when η is small. If the failure to regulate the externality is viewed as a
government failure, a news report that the externality is serious may mitigate a government
failure when (9) is satisfied.
The support for regulation also depends on the extent to which citizens internalize the
externality. The derivative is
dv
0
(θ
+
,s
+
)
dη
=
θ
+
Nn
α(n +1)?v(1?αs
+
)
(?v(1?αs
+
)?(2?α?s
+
)θ
+
N). (10)
If the externality is costly (θ
+
N>?v), the derivative is negative, so greater other-regardedness
reduces the support for regulation. Support for regulation decreases because an increase in
η shifts demand downward, which lessens the effect of the externality. To the extent that
15
moral suasion can affect η, the news media as well as the activist and the industry have
incentives to offer moral arguments to persuade consumers to act or not to act privately
in the market. Moral suasion is not treated as a strategy here but instead is considered
qualitatively in Section X.
D. Media Influence
Basedontheirpriorinformation
ˉ
θ = pθ
H
+(1?p)θ
L
, citizens with v<v
?
(s
+
,
ˉ
θ)donot
purchase and prefer regulation s
+
= s,andthosewithv≥v
?
(s
+
,
ˉ
θ) purchase and a subset of
them, those with v ∈ [v
?
(s
+
,
ˉ
θ),v
o
(s
+
,
ˉ
θ)), prefer regulation. Those with higher valuations
prefer no regulation. The status quo of no regulation is assumed to be the collective choice
with prior information, which requires that v
o
(s,
ˉ
θ)<γ?v or
?v
parenleftBig
γ?
1
n +1
parenrightBig
>
ˉ
θN
(n +1)α?v(1?αs)
parenleftBigparenleftBig
n?η+(n+1)
parenleftBig
η?
1
N
parenrightBigparenrightBig
?v(1?αs)?(2?α?s)n
ˉ
θηN
parenrightBig
.
(11)
Consequently, s
+
= 0 corresponds to θ
+
=
ˉ
θ.
For the media to influence the collective choice, a proportion γ of the public must
prefer regulation when the media reports that the issue is serious. Letting the mean of the
public’s posterior beliefs be denoted by
ˉ
θ
H
when the media reports that the issue is serious,
regulation s
+
= s is preferred if and only if
ˉ
θ
H
N
(n +1)α?v(1?αs)
parenleftBigparenleftBig
n?η+(n+1)
parenleftBig
η?
1
N
parenrightBigparenrightBig
?v(1?αs)?(2?α?s)n
ˉ
θ
H
ηN
parenrightBig
≥
parenleftBig
γ?
1
n +1
parenrightBig
?v,
(12)
where s
+
= s corresponds to θ
+
=
ˉ
θ
H
. If (11) and (12) are satisfied, the news media
influences the collective choice when it reports that the issue is serious.
13
This situation is
illustrated in Figure 3.
VI. The News Media: Subscribers and Sources
13
A necessary and sufficient condition for both (11) and (12) to be satisfied is
(
ˉ
θ
H
?
ˉ
θ)
bracketleftBigparenleftBig
n?η +(n +1)
parenleftBig
η?
1
N
parenrightBigparenrightBig
?v(1?αs)?(2?α?s)(
ˉ
θ
H
+
ˉ
θ)nηN
bracketrightBig
>
s
parenleftBig
n?η +(n +1)
parenleftBig
η?
1
N
parenrightBig
α?v?nηN
ˉ
θ
H
parenrightBig
.
This is satisfied when
ˉ
θ
H
>
ˉ
θ, which will be the case in equilibrium, and (10) is satisfied for
θ
+
=
ˉ
θ
H
+
ˉ
θ
2
.
16
A. Subscribers
The media influences private politics because purchase decisions depend on the in-
formation provided; i.e., v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)dependsonthenewsreportthroughθ
+
. The media
influences public politics if its report affects the collective choice between regulation s and
no regulation as considered in Section V.D. The pivotal voter, however, must receive the
report of the news media. Public and private politics depend on who and how many citizens
see the news report.
The members of the public must have a reason to spend the time to comprehend
the news report. They may do so if subscribing to the media’s service is expected to
benefit them by allowing them to make better decisions or because the news report has
entertainment value.
14
The news media’s report is also a public good, since in principle
a subscriber could share the information with others. The case considered here is that
in which the news report spills over to all citizens. Because of this spillover the revenue
of the media is problematic. Every citizen prefers to free-ride, yet if no one subscribes
to the media service, no news report will be forthcoming. One perspective is that those
who subscribe are those who expect to benefit in their private decisions. The media then
prices its service given its potential subscribers, and those who expect to benefit by more
that the price less the entertainment value subscribe. Appendix B presents a model of this
perspective.
Citizens must subscribe to the media service prior to receiving a news report, and hence
the media’s revenue is independent of the report it eventually provides.
15
The subscribers
are those citizens who expect to benefit in their private decisions by at least the price
charged by the media less the entertainment value. The expectations of citizens are assumed
to be rational and consistent with the equilibrium strategies of the interest groups and
the news media. As indicated in Appendix B, the set of subscribers is increasing in the
entertainment value and in the extent to which consumers internalize the externality. The
profit of the news media is increasing in the expectations of extreme reports the media
might provide.
B. The Media’s Sources
14
This perspective is also adopted in Bovitz, Druckman, and Lupia.
15
This would not be the case in a repeated game.
17
When the media receives hard information, it is assumed to report that information
to the public. If it concealed hard information provided by a source, it could be exposed
for having distorted that information. Such exposure is assumed to be prohibitively costly
to the media. As indicated in Section IX, if the media faced no risk of exposure if it
concealed hard information, the equilibrium would be qualitatively similar to that in which
the media reports hard information faithfully. That is, the event in which hard information
is concealed by a source is the same event in which the media would conceal. The same
conclusion results if the media investigates and finds hard information. Consequently, the
media is assumed to report hard information. The only opportunity for discretion by the
media thus occurs when neither the industry nor the activist provides hard information
and either investigative journalism is not conducted or an investigation is conducted and
it is unsuccessful. That is, the news media exercises discretion in its report only when it
has no hard information.
Theactivistandthefirmscouldcommunicatedirectlywithcitizensratherthanthrough
the news media. However, because of their incentives to advocate their side of the issue,
the credibility of their communications would be in doubt. Furthermore, citizens may have
to incur prohibitively high costs to verify the content of the communications. In contrast,
themediamaybeabletoevaluatemoreefficientlytheinformationpresentedbytheactivist
and the industry. In addition, the media can investigate the issue if the activist and the
industry provide no hard information. The media thus both reduces costs for the public
and adds credibility through its new reports. Moreover, the news media can be a low-cost
means of disseminating information to the public. The activist and the industry thus are
assumed to communicate through the news media.
Given the results of their searches, in the communication stage the activist and the
firms acting as an industry independently send to the news media a message m
i
∈M,i=
A,F,whereA denotesactivistandF denotes firms and the message space is M =
{θ
L
,θ
H
,φ} with φ denoting no information. If a search by either the activist or the in-
dustry is unsuccessful, the only message it may send is m
i
= φ. If a search is successful,
the activist and the industry are not required to report their information; i.e., they can
conceal it by sending the message m
i
= φ. The activist and the industry thus can advocate
their position by communicating favorable information to the media, but neither is forced
18
to provide unfavorable information.
16
A communication strategy of the industry is a probability distribution over the message
set M.Thestateθ
L
is favorable to the industry, so if its search reveals that state, the
industry has a dominant strategy of sending m
F
= θ
L
, in which case there will be no
regulation. If the industry’s search reveals the unfavorable state θ
H
, it may send the
message m
F
∈{θ
H
,φ}. That is, the industry cannot fabricate information, e.g., that
θ = θ
L
, but it can remain silent about θ
H
by sending m
F
= φ. Let the probability that
the industry sends m
F
= φ when θ
H
is observed be denoted by ρ
F
∈ [0,1].
Similarly, the state θ
H
is favorable to the activist, and if its search reveals that state, it
has a dominant strategy of sending the message m
A
= θ
H
.Ifθ = θ
L
, the activist conceals
(m
A
= φ) the unfavorable information with probability ρ
A
∈ [0,1] and sends m
A
= θ
H
with probability 1?ρ
A
.
The activist and the industry may choose not to conceal unfavorable information if
the media can independently search for information through investigative journalism. The
information the media obtains from an investigation is denoted m
M
∈{θ
L
,θ
H
,φ}.Ifits
investigation is successful and one of the sources might have concealed information, the
media can so state in its news report. This harms the reputation of the source that may
have concealed the information, which mitigates the incentive to conceal information.
C. Media Beliefs
The media has no hard information when it receives the messages m
A
= φ and m
F
= φ
and either does not investigate (m =(m
A
= φ,m
F
= φ)) or investigates unsuccessfully
and has the information m
prime
=(m
A
= φ,m
F
= φ,m
M
= φ). The media’s beliefs p
φ
when
it does not investigate are
p
φ
= Pr(θ = θ
H
| m
A
= m
F
= φ)=
p(1?q + qρ
F
)
p(1?q + qρ
F
)+(1?p)(1?q + qρ
A
)
. (13)
It is straightforward to show that when it unsuccessfully investigates Pr(θ = θ
H
| m
A
=
m
F
= m
M
= φ)=p
φ
, since the probability q
M
of a successful investigation is independent
of the state. The media’s beliefs are thus the same when its sources provide no hard
information and when it investigates and receives no information or does not investigate.
16
See Dewatripoint and Tirole (1999) for a theory of advocacy.
19
The media’s beliefs have posterior mean
ˉ
θ
o
given by
ˉ
θ
o
=
p(1?q + qρ
F
)θ
H
+(1?p)(1?q + qρ
A
)θ
L
p(1?q + qρ
F
)+(1?p)(1?q + qρ
A
)
, (14)
which is strictly increasing in ρ
F
and strictly decreasing in ρ
A
. That is, if the industry
conceals with higher probability, it is more likely that m
F
= φ resulted from state θ
H
.If
the activist concealed with higher probability, it is more likely that m
A
= φ resulted from
state θ
L
. Also, the higher is the quality q of the search the greater is the opportunity for
the activist and the industry to conceal unfavorable information. The posterior mean is
strictly increasing in q if and only if the industry conceals with a higher probability than
the activist. As demonstrated below, in equilibrium only the activist conceals, so
ˉ
θ
o
is
decreasing in the quality of the search.
The difference between the media’s posterior mean and the prior mean is
ˉ
θ
o
?
ˉ
θ =
p(1?p)q(ρ
F
?ρ
A
)(θ
H
?θ
L
)
p(1?q + qρ
F
)+(1?p)(1?q + qρ
A
)
. (15)
The direction of influence of the activist and the industry is as expected. The greater the
probability the activist (industry) conceals the smaller (larger) is
ˉ
θ
o
?
ˉ
θ.
D. News Reports and the Public’s Beliefs
To identify the public’s beliefs, the report set of the media must first be identified;
i.e., the set of reports the news media can effectively send. If the media sends a report
r/∈{θ
L
,θ
H
}, the public, which is rational, infers that the media has no hard information,
so if r ∈ (θ
L
,θ
H
), the public makes the correct inference
ˉ
θ
o
about θ. Consequently, if the
media has no hard information, its effective set of reports is M = {φ
L
,φ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
}.Anybias
by the news media thus must take the form of reporting r = θ
H
or r = θ
L
when it has no
hard information.
The public’s beliefs depend on whether the media conducts investigative journalism,
which is not observable to the public, and what it reports when it has no hard information.
Let ξ ∈ [0,1] denote the probability the media investigates when (m
A
= m
F
= φ), and let
ω denote the probability the media reports r = θ
H
and 1 ? ω denote the probability the
media reports r =
ˉ
θ
o
when m
A
= m
F
= φ and the media does not investigate. Similarly,
let λ denote the probability the media reports r = θ
H
and 1?λ denote the probability the
20
media reports r =
ˉ
θ
o
when the media investigates unsuccessfully. The public’s posterior
beliefs then are
Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
)=
pPr(r = θ
H
| θ = θ
H
)
pPr(r = θ
H
| θ = θ
H
)+(1?p)Pr(r = θ
H
| θ = θ
L
)
, (16)
where
Pr(r = θ
H
| θ = θ
L
)=((1?q)qρ
A
+(1?q)
2
)(ξ(1?q
M
)λ +(1?ξ)ω), (17)
and
Pr(r = θ
H
| θ = θ
H
)=q(2?q?ρ
F
(1?q))+(1?q)(1?q(1?ρ
F
))(ξq
M
+ξ(1?q
M
)λ+(1?ξ)ω).
(18)
The probability Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
) in (16) is strictly decreasing in ρ
A
if ω>0or
λ>0and,ifω<1orλ<1, is strictly decreasing in ρ
F
.Givenr = θ
H
, a higher probability
of concealment by the activist reduces the confidence of the public that θ = θ
H
,sincethe
activist conceals when θ = θ
L
. A higher probability ρ
F
of concealment by the industry
reduces the public’s posterior probability that the issue is serious because there is a lower
probability of being presented with hard information that θ = θ
H
. If, however, the media
reports r = θ
H
with probability ω = λ = 1 whenever it has no hard information, the
probability in (16) is constant in ρ
F
.
If ω = λ = 1, that is, the media biases its report whenever possible, the probability
Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
)isincreasinginξ. That is, investigative journalism increases the
confidence of the public in the report because the opportunity for bias is smaller. The
higher the probability (ω or λ) that the media biased its report, however, the lower is the
probability in (16). The public thus exhibits skepticism.
The public’s beliefs
ˉ
θ
H
about the posterior mean when it receives a report r = θ
H
are
ˉ
θ
H
= Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
)θ
H
+(1?Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
))θ
L
= θ
L
+(θ
H
?θ
L
)Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
).
(19)
From (16)-(18) the public’s posterior mean inherits the properties of Pr(θ = θ
H
| r = θ
H
).
The posterior mean
ˉ
θ
H
is strictly decreasing in ω and λ, so the more likely is the news media
to bias its report, the more skeptical is the public. Conversely, the higher is the quality q
M
21
of the media’s investigation the higher is
ˉ
θ
H
, since the public has more confidence in the
media’s report. If the media reports r = θ
H
with probability ω = λ =1whenithasno
hard information,
ˉ
θ
H
is constant in ρ
F
and is strictly increasing in ξ.
E. Exposing the News Media for Bias
If the news media biases its report when it has no hard information, the activist or
the industry could expose the bias if it had hard information. Neither, however, has the
incentive to do so. The opportunity for exposure is when the activist or the industry has
hard information and concealed it, so the party that concealed the information would be
exposing itself as well. More importantly, the party that concealed the information has
no incentive to expose the media, since that would negate the reason for the concealment.
Suppose that the activist concealed the unfavorable information θ
L
and the news media
reported r = θ
H
. This report serves the interests of the activist, and hence it has no
incentive to expose the bias. If the media were to report r = θ
L
, the activist could not
expose the media because the report was accurate. Similarly, if the industry concealed
the unfavorable information θ
H
, it has no incentive to expose a report r = θ
L
and cannot
expose an accurate report r = θ
H
. Consequently, the media faces no risk of exposure.
VII. News Reports and Investigative Journalism
A. Media Preferences
As indicated in Section III, the news media is widely viewed as biased, although poll
respondents disagree about the nature and direction of that bias. Bias could result from
an ideological preference for regulation among the journalists in or the owners of the news
organization or because of their beliefs about the seriousness of the issue. Bias in such
a case comes directly from individual preferences or beliefs and begs the question of why
journalists and the news organization have those preferences or beliefs. The approach taken
here is to represent the preferences of the news media in terms of fundamental measures of
profits and journalistic considerations.
The media as a private institution provides information to the public to help people
make better decisions both in their roles as consumers and their roles as citizens. The
consequences of their decisions will be represented by aggregate public welfare W,whichis
identified below. The media also has a role in discovering misrepresentation in information
22
provided by its sources. Investigative journalism is the instrument for uncovering misrep-
resentation, but investigative journalism is costly. These considerations are represented by
the utility U
M
of the media specified as
U
M
= pi
?
M
+ ξ(?c + χW
ξ=1
+ δJ)+(1?ξ)χW
ξ=0
, (20)
where pi
?
M
is profit as identified in Appendix B, c is the cost of investigating, χ is the
weight given by the media to aggregate public welfare, J is the utility from journalistic
performance, δ is the weight attached to it, and W
ξ=1
and W
ξ=0
are, respectively, the
aggregate welfare if the media investigates or not. As indicated in Appendix B, profits
result from subscriptions based on rational expectations of subsequent media reports and
hence are unaffected ex post by the media’s investigative journalism or news report. The
media’s journalistic preferences are specified below.
B. News Reports
The media’s opportunity for influence is when the activist and the industry provide
no hard information and the media either does not investigate or investigates without
success. Consider the strategy of biasing its report by reporting r = θ
H
when it has no
hard information. This strategy has two implications. First, the news media may have a
weaker incentive to investigate because investigating reduces the probability it will have the
opportunity to exercise its discretion. Second, the activist may have a greater incentive to
conceal θ = θ
L
so as to increase the opportunity of the news media to exercise its discretion
in the direction the activist prefers. The industry has no counteractive incentive because
it can decrease the media’s opportunity for discretion only by reducing the probability it
conceals unfavorable information θ
H
. Consequently, there is a synergy between the media’s
incentive to bias its report and the group whose interests are advantaged by the bias. That
group has an incentive to conceal unfavorable information, so as to increase the opportunity
for the media to bias its report.
Journalistic standards and the media’s responsibility as a institution serving the pub-
lic, however, call for unbiased reports.
17
If the news media is concerned about violating
standards by biasing its report, it may incur a cost in the form of a reduction in employee
17
Codes of ethics and responsibilities for journalists can be found at www.asne.org/ideas/codes.
Also see the Poynter Institute Web site www.poynter.org.
23
morale or a loss of pride in its professionalism. Goldberg (2002), however, argued that the
news media biases its reports but does not understand that it is doing so. The media could,
for example, just believe that a report r = θ
H
is warranted when it has no hard information
because that helps mitigate the externality. Because the cost of providing a biased report
is unclear, only a bound on that cost will be identified.
The media’s news report comes after its decision to investigate, so the report depends
only on aggregate public welfare. The media evaluates aggregate public welfare in terms
of its own information, which when it has no hard information is the posterior mean
ˉ
θ
o
in
(14). The media’s evaluation W(s
+
,θ
+
,
?
θ) of aggregate public welfare when it has no hard
information, has beliefs
?
θ ∈{θ
L
,θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
}, and induces beliefs θ
+
∈{
ˉ
θ
L
,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
} of the public
is
18
W(s
+
,θ
+
,
?
θ)=
integraldisplay
?v
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)
((1 ? αs
+
) ? (1 ? s
+
)(ηN ? 1)θ
+
)v
N
?v
dv
?
integraldisplay
?v
0
(1 ?s
+
)
?
θN
parenleftBig
1 ?
v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)
?v
parenrightBig
N
?v
dv
= X(s
+
,θ
+
)
bracketleftBig
(1 ?αs
+
)
parenleftBig
?v + v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)
2
parenrightBig
? (1 ? s
+
)(ηN ? 1)θ
+
? (1 ?s
+
)
?
θN
bracketrightBig
.
This is linear and strictly decreasing in
?
θ.
To determine the direction of possible media bias, consider first the alternative of
reporting r = θ
L
when the media has no hard information. This would result in no
regulation, since the posterior mean
ˉ
θ
L
is less than
ˉ
θ
o
. In addition, more consumers would
purchase, worsening the externality. Consequently, the media will not report r = θ
L
when
it has no hard information. The media thus reports r = θ
L
only when it has received
hard information, so Pr(θ = θ
L
| r = θ
L
)=1. This implies that the conditional mean is
ˉ
θ
L
= θ
L
.
If the media reports r =
ˉ
θ
o
, the public believes that the media has no hard information.
As will be demonstrated below, in equilibrium the industry has no incentive to conceal, so
ρ
F
=0.Then,from(15)
ˉ
θ
o
<
ˉ
θ, so citizens choose not to regulate.
If the media reports r = θ
H
, the public understands that the report could be biased
and has posterior beliefs
ˉ
θ
H
given in (19). Although
ˉ
θ
H
<θ
H
, the posterior beliefs are still
18
Aggregate welfare includes the profit of the firms, which are assumed to be owned by
the public. The media’s profits are not included, since they are determined ex ante and are
independent of its subsequent actions.
24
greater than the prior mean; i.e.,
ˉ
θ
H
>
ˉ
θ. The public thus can be influenced by the report
even though it knows that the information might be biased.
The media then prefers to report r = θ
H
when it has no hard information if W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
)?
W(0,
ˉ
θ
o
,
ˉ
θ
o
) is positive. This condition is
W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
)?W(0,
ˉ
θ
o
,
ˉ
θ
o
)=X(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)
bracketleftBig
(1?αs)
parenleftBig
?v + v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)
2
parenrightBig
?(1?s)(ηN ?1)
ˉ
θ
H
?(1?s)
ˉ
θ
o
N
bracketrightBig
?X(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)
bracketleftBig
?v + v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)
2
?(ηN ?1)
ˉ
θ
o
?
ˉ
θ
o
N
bracketrightBig
.
(21)
To illustrate this condition, consider the case in which α = 1 and consumers do not take
into account (η =
1
N
) the effect of the externality on others. Then, (21) is
W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
)?W(0,
ˉ
θ
o
,
ˉ
θ
o
)=
nN
(n +1)
2
?v
parenleftBig
(n +2)?v?
ˉ
θ
o
(2(n +1)N ?n)
2
parenrightBig
((1?s)(?v?
ˉ
θ
H
)?(?v?
ˉ
θ
o
)),
which is positive when N is large. The media then is influential, which is the case of interest
here.
When the media reports r = θ
H
when it has no hard information, the maximum cost
?c
J
of violating journalistic standards the media is willing to incur is defined by
?c
J
≡ χ(W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
)?W(0,
ˉ
θ
o
,
ˉ
θ
o
)).
If the cost is greater than ?c
J
, the media reports truthfully. When the cost is below ?c
J
,the
media reports r = θ
H
with probabilities ω
?
=1andλ
?
= 1. The media prefers to bias
its report because of its effects on private and public politics. Through private politics the
report reduces demand, and through public politics it leads to regulation which increases
public welfare. The remainder of this section considers the case in which the cost is less than
the bound, so the media biases (λ
?
= ω
?
= 1) its report when it has no hard information.
C. Journalistic Performance and Investigative Journalism
The media may gain prestige if through investigative journalism it uncovers conceal-
ment by the activist or the industry. The media cannot uncover concealment without error,
however, because it does not observe the information received by its sources. The media
knows the equilibrium strategies of the activist and the industry, however, and knows that
25
the activist will never conceal information θ
H
and the industry will never conceal θ
L
.Con-
sequently, if the media investigates and observes θ
H
and the industry has sent the message
m
F
= φ, the industry may have concealed.
If the media receives the messages (m
A
= φ,m
F
= φ,m
M
= θ
H
), it believes the
industry concealed with probability ˉρ
F
given by
ˉρ
F
=
qρ
F
qρ
F
+1?q
. (22)
Similarly, the posterior probability ˉρ
A
the activist concealed when (m
A
= φ,m
F
= φ,m
M
=
θ
L
)is
ˉρ
A
=
qρ
A
qρ
A
+1?q
. (23)
Journalistic performance J in (20) will be represented as the gain in prestige for the
news media from exposing concealment by its sources, weighted by the posterior probability
that the source concealed information. Letting b
i
,i= A,F, represent the prestige, the gains
from exposing the activist and the industry, respectively, are ˉρ
A
b
A
and ˉρ
F
b
F
.
The media is assumed to investigate only when it has no hard information. The
expected utility EU
M
(ξ) of the media as a function of the probability ξ of investigating
conditional on (m
A
= φ,m
F
= φ)isthen
19
EU
M
(ξ)=pi
?
M
+ ξ
bracketleftBig
q
M
parenleftBig
p
φ
(δb
F
ˉρ
F
?c + χW(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,θ
H
)) + (1?p
φ
)(δb
A
ˉρ
A
?c+ χW(0,θ
L
,θ
L
))
parenrightBig
+(1?q
M
)(?c + χW(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
))
bracketrightBig
+(1?ξ)χW(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
),
(24)
where p
φ
is given in (13), W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,θ
H
) is the media’s evaluation of aggregate welfare when
its search reveals θ = θ
H
and it reports r = θ
H
and W(0,θ
L
,θ
L
)iswelfarewhenitssearch
reveals θ = θ
L
.
20
19
Note that the media receives b
i
,i = A,F, only if it investigates and not when one
interest group provides hard information and the other provides no information. If one
of its sources provided hard information, investigative journalism would be meaningless.
Moreover, professionalism would likely prevent the media from falsely claiming that it had
investigated.
20
In (20), W
ξ=0
= W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
), and W
ξ=1
= q
M
(p
φ
W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,θ
H
)+(1?p
φ
)W(0,θ
L
,θ
L
))+
(1?q
M
)W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
).
26
The media’s optimal strategy ξ
?
for investigative journalism satisfies
ξ
?
?
?
?
?
?
?
∈ (0,1) if
dEU
M
(ξ)
dξ
=0
=0 if
dEU
M
(ξ)
dξ
≤ 0 ? ξ ∈ (0,1]
=1 if
dEU
M
(ξ)
dξ
> 0 ? ξ ∈ [0,1),
where from (24)
dEU
M
(ξ)
dξ
= q
M
bracketleftbig
p
φ
δb
F
ˉρ
F
+(1?p
φ
)δb
A
ˉρ
A
+ χ?W
bracketrightbig
?c (25)
and ?W reflects the informational consequences of an investigation or
?W ≡ p
φ
W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,θ
H
)+(1?p
φ
)W(0,θ
L
,θ
L
)?W(s,
ˉ
θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
).
The sign of ?W cannot be determined unambiguously, but the expected demand with a
successful investigation can be shown to be greater than with an unsuccessful investigation.
Investigative journalism is thus motivated by uncovering concealment by the activist or the
industry and possibly by greater expected public welfare due to the better information it
provides. If ?W<0, the only incentive to investigate is due to journalistic performance.
VIII. Communication: Competition Between the Activist and the Industry
The activist and the industry compete to influence the public by sending messages to
the news media. Each has an opportunity to conceal unfavorable information and thus
present a more favorable case to the media. The opportunity to conceal unfavorable infor-
mation, however, occurs only if the other player has not observed that information. For
example, suppose the state is θ
H
. If the industry observed θ
H
, it could send the message
m
F
= φ. If the activist observed θ
H
, however, it has a dominant strategy of sending
m
A
= θ
H
. Consequently, the industry can conceal the state only if the activist does not
observe it. In addition, if the activist’s search reveals no information, the media may in-
vestigate and observe m
M
= θ
H
, which would then cast suspicion on the veracity of the
industry’s message m
F
= φ.
The communication strategies of the activist and the industry also depend on the
media’s reporting strategy. In the case considered, the media reports r = θ
H
whenever it
has no hard information, so the public’s beliefs
ˉ
θ
H
are constant in ρ
F
. The industry then
cannot influence the report received by the public. The public’s beliefs
ˉ
θ
H
are decreasing
27
in the activist’s concealment strategy ρ
A
, so the public becomes more skeptical of a news
report r = θ
H
when the activist conceals θ = θ
L
with higher probability. This results
because concealment by the activist gives the media a greater opportunity to provide a
biased report. The news media’s incentive to bias its report also influences its investigation
strategy,whichinturnaffectstheconcealmentstrategies.
Concealment poses a risk. For example, the industry may incur reputation damage
H
F
≥0 if it is suspected of having concealed; i.e., the media reports r = θ
H
and the industry
sent m
F
= φ. Thatdamagewillbeassumedtooccurthroughthenewsreportandin
proportion to the posterior probability ˉρ
F
that the industry concealed given either m
A
= θ
H
or (m
A
= φ,m
M
= θ
H
), which is given in (22). The expected utility U
F
(ρ
F
;m
i
= θ
H
,i=
AorM) of the industry conditional on having observed θ
H
and concealed with probability
ρ
F
is
U
F
(ρ
F
;m
i
= θ
H
,i= AorM)=npi
?
i
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)? ˉρ
F
H
F
, (26)
since the media reports r = θ
H
with probability 1 when it receives m
A
= θ
H
or m
M
= θ
H
and regulation s results from the public politics.
To determine the industry’s optimal concealment strategy, suppose the industry ob-
served θ
H
, concealed it, and the media investigated with probability ξ. With probability
q
M
the media observes θ
H
, in which case the utility of the industry is that in (26). With
probability 1?q
M
the media observes nothing and reports r = θ
H
, so the industry’s profit
is given by the first term in (26). This is also the outcome if the media does not investigate.
Consequently, regardless of the concealment strategy of the industry the report received by
thepublicisr = θ
H
, and the industry’s profits are npi
?
i
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
). Since the industry suffers
damagetoitsreputationifitconcealsandtheactivistorthemediareceiveshardinfor-
mation that the state is θ
H
, the industry cannot gain through concealment. Consequently,
ρ
?
F
= 0 is optimal.
The activist is in a different position. If it conceals unfavorable information θ
L
,it
increases the opportunity for the media to report r = θ
H
. This opportunity is present only
in the events in which the industry observed nothing and the media did not investigate
or investigated and observed nothing. Concealment also poses a risk to the activist if the
industry sends m
F
= θ
L
or the media investigates and observes m
M
= θ
L
. The damage to
the reputation of the activist is denoted H
A
≥0, and the expected damage is assumed to be
28
proportional to the probability ˉρ
A
in (23) that the activist concealed.
The activist is assumed to have preferences over both regulation and the state, but
the activist conceals only when it observes θ
L
, so its preferences are conditional on θ = θ
L
.
The activist has an incentive to conceal only if it prefers regulation s with r = θ
H
to no
regulation with r = θ
L
. In this case, its preferences satisfy U
A
(
ˉ
θ
H
)>U
A
(θ
L
), where the
activist’s utility function is denoted by U
A
(·).
21
The expected utility EU
A
(θ
L
) of the activist conditional on having concealed θ
L
is
EU
A
(θ
L
)=(q +(1?q)ξ
?
q
M
)(U
A
(θ
L
) ? ˉρ
A
H
A
)+(1? q)(1 ?ξ
?
q
M
)U
A
(
ˉ
θ
H
),
where the probability q corresponds to m
F
= θ
L
and the probability (1?q)ξq
M
corresponds
to the media investigating successfully given m
F
= φ. The expected utility EU
A
(ρ
A
;θ
L
)
of the activist as a function of its concealment strategy is
EU
A
(ρ
A
;θ
L
)=ρ
A
EU
A
(θ
L
)+(1?ρ
A
)U
A
(θ
L
).
Thederivativeis
dEU
A
(θ
L
)
dρ
A
=(1?q)(1 ? ξ
?
q
M
)(U
A
(
ˉ
θ
H
) ?U
A
(θ
L
)) ? (q +(1?q)ξ
?
q
M
)ˉρ
A
H
A
. (27)
The first term in (27) is positive, and the second term is negative and represents a check
on the incentive to conceal resulting from the possible damage to the activist’s reputation.
Evaluating (27) at ρ
A
=0yields
dEU
A
(θ
L
)
dρ
A
|ρ
A
=0
=(1?q)(1?ξ
?
q
M
)(U
A
(
ˉ
θ
H
)?U
A
(θ
L
)) > 0,
so the equilibrium concealment probability ρ
?
A
is positive. The activist thus conceals unfa-
vorable information with positive probability. This results regardless of whether the media
investigates. The optimal concealment probability equals 1 if the damage H
A
is small,
and a greater H
A
can result in ρ
?
A
∈ (0,1). An interior equilibrium then can exist if the
derivative in (25) equals 0 for (ξ
?
,ρ
?
A
) ∈ (0,1)×(0,1).
The equilibrium concealment and investigative journalism strategies identified by (25)
and (27) could take a variety of forms. The activist conceals with probability 1 if the
21
For example, aggregate welfare could be greater with regulation when θ = θ
L
.
29
damage to its reputation is no greater than the bound
ˉ
H
A
given by
ˉ
H
A
≡
(1?q)(1?ξ
?
q
M
)(U
A
(
ˉ
θ
H
)?U
A
(θ
L
))
q(q +(1?q)ξ
?
q
M
)
, (28)
where ξ
?
is the corresponding investigation probability.
22
Then, from (25) if the cost of
investigative journalism is low, the media investigates with probability 1; i.e.,
c ≤ q
M
((1?p
φ
)δb
A
q + χ?W
|
ξ=1
).
Consequently, for some parameter values the equilibrium is (ρ
?
A
=1,ξ
?
=1).Asthequality
q
M
of the investigation increases, however, the bound
ˉ
H
A
in(28)goesto0whenξ
?
=1,
in which case ρ
?
A
<1. Similarly, for higher c, ξ
?
<1.
In the equilibrium the public is skeptical of the report r = θ
H
because the activist
conceals θ = θ
L
with positive probability. That is, using (18) and (19) with ρ
?
F
=0,
λ
?
=1,andω
?
= 1, the posterior mean is
ˉ
θ
H
<θ
H
. If off the equilibrium path the media
were to report r ∈ (θ
L
,θ
H
), the public would believe that the media’s posterior mean was
ˉ
θ
o
,andfrom(15)
ˉ
θ
o
<
ˉ
θ. The public then would not choose regulation. Regulation thus
results with ex ante probability
Pr(s)=p +(1?p)(1?q)(1?q(1?q(1?ρ
?
A
+ ρ
?
A
ξ
?
q
M
)). (20)
IX. Concealment by the Media
The media may have the opportunity and ability to conceal hard information provided
by one of its sources, although professionalism may prevent it from doing so. When pro-
fessionalism does not prevent concealment, the media may face the risk of exposure by
one of its sources. This risk could take the form of a lawsuit for defamation or the source
taking its information to the public or to its allies in government. Even if that were not
the case, the media may have no incentive to provide a report inconsistent with the hard
information it receives. This results from the media’s preferences for regulation when its
beliefs are θ = θ
H
.
22
In this case, if the media observes an off-the-equilibrium-path message m
A
= θ
L
,its
beliefs are assumed to be that θ = θ
L
. Since it then “knows” the state, its report would be
r = θ
L
.
30
The hard information messages the media may receive from its sources are presented
in Table 1, and associated with each message pair is whether the media has an incentive
to conceal. The first column pertains to the case in which the public’s welfare is greater
(W(0,θ
L
,θ
L
)≥W(s,θ
+
,θ
L
)) without regulation when θ = θ
L
, and the second column is
the case in which welfare is greater with regulation. When regulation is not preferred in
θ = θ
L
, the media has no incentive to conceal because a truthful report results in the
maximal public welfare. Also, when θ = θ
H
, the media also has no incentive to conceal.
Table 1
Concealment by the Media
Incentive to Conceal
Messages (s
+
=0) (s
+
= s)
(m
A
= θ
H
,m
F
= θ
H
)no no
(m
A
= θ
H
,m
F
= φ)no no
(m
A
= θ
L
,m
F
= θ
L
)no yes
(m
A
= θ
L
,m
F
= φ)no yes
(m
A
= φ,m
F
= θ
H
)no no
(m
A
= φ,m
F
= θ
L
)no yes
When regulation is preferred in θ = θ
L
, the media has an incentive to conceal a
message m
i
= θ
L
,i = A,F, and report r = θ
H
, resulting in regulation. If the media
conceals the message m
F
= θ
L
, however, the industry would expose it, which is assumed
to be prohibitively costly to the media.
23
Only in the case (m
A
= θ
L
,m
F
= φ)will
concealment not be exposed. This case, however, is the one in which concealment takes
place in the equilibrium characterized above. The qualitative effect on private and public
politics would thus be the same whether the activist or the media concealed θ
L
.
The same conclusion results if the media can conceal the results of its own investigative
journalism. It has no incentive to do so when m
M
= θ
H
,andwhenm
M
= θ
L
,ithasan
23
For example, NBC’s Dateline fabricated pickup truck fires due to side-impact collisions
and was exposed by General Motors, leading to the firing of the head of NBC News and
others. See the case “General Motors Like a Rock (A)” by Keith Krehbiel in Baron (2003a),
pp. 85-88.
31
incentive to conceal only when it prefers regulation when θ = θ
L
. If it prefers regulation, the
media faces a risk of exposure if the industry had sent m
F
= θ
L
. Consequently, the media
has an incentive to conceal only when the industry report is m
F
= φ. But, in this case the
media has no incentive to investigate. That is, if m
A
= θ
L
and m
F
= φ, the media knows
the state and has no incentive to investigate. If m
A
= θ
H
and m
F
= φ, the media also
has no incentive to investigate, since a truthful report results in regulation. Consequently,
the only incentive for the media to investigate is due to journalistic performance to expose
concealment from its sources when neither provides information. This is the case considered
above in Section VII.C.
X. Moral Suasion
The strategies of the activist, the firms, and the news media could affect the private
and collective decisions of the public not only through beliefs but also through preferences.
For example, greater recognition of the externality could lead some citizen consumers to
assume a duty to internalize a portion of the externality. For example, voluntary recycling
has become widespread over the past two decades as a result of the recognition of the
externalities associated with a variety of products. In the model, this is represented by the
parameter η, which could depend on the treatment given to the issue in the news report.
This treatment could take the form of normative arguments that affect the preferences of
the public beyond the information about the seriousness θ of the externality contained in
the news report. When the media treats the issue in a normative manner, it is participating
in private politics through moral suasion. In the model, moral suasion that affects η also
affects citizens’ preferences for regulation, so moral suasion affects public politics. The
responsiveness of citizen consumers to the media’s treatment of the issue also could provide
an incentive for informational bias, and this could provide an incentive for the activist to
conceal unfavorable information.
The activist and the industry could also offer normative arguments, but because of
credibility concerns their arguments might not have the same influence as those of the
news media. Moral suasion still is attempted by activists and firms, however. The cost
of contacting the public through advertisements is moderate, particularly when the news
media views the advertisements themselves as newsworthy. For example, in January 2003
the Detroit Project led by Arianna Huffington spent nearly $200,000 for television adver-
32
tisements linking SUVs to the support of terrorism. The ads asked “What is your SUV
doing to our national security?” Showing armed terrorists in a desert, the ads stated “And
these are the terrorists who get money from those countries every time George fills up
his SUV.” Other campaigns were also underway. The Evangelical Environmental Network
(EEN) declared that “transportation is a moral issue” and ran TV advertisements asking,
“What would Jesus drive?” The answer is not an SUV.
24
Also, “Earth on Empty, a group
of Boston artists, plasters fake parking tickets on S.U.V. windshields that instruct drivers
to ‘try to get honest with yourself.’ ... The posters at a recent antiwar rally in San Fran-
cisco said, ‘Draft S.U.V. drivers first.’”
25
Whether these arguments have influenced either
private or public politics is unclear, but activists as well as their targets frequently make
such arguments to the public.
In the context of the model, η could be represented as an increasing function of the
forcefulness of moral suasion about the importance of internalizing some portion of the ex-
ternality; i.e., about other-regardedness. Then, based on the above analysis, moral suasion
has the following effects:
1. Moral suasion reduces the demand for the product and hence the harm from the exter-
nality. Moral suasion is thus a substitute for regulation.
2. Moral suasion decreases the public support for regulation because it reduces the extent
of the externality. Moral suasion thus affects public politics.
3. Moral suasion can eliminate the informational influence of the news media, and hence the
incentive to bias its report, if the pivotal voter no longer prefers regulation when r = θ
H
.
4. Moral suasion shifts downward the demand function for the product which results in a
lower price and lower profits in the industry.
5. Moral suasion increases the profit of the news media by shifting the demand function;
i.e., increasing the number of subscribers and allowing a higher price to be charged.
26
Moral suasion through the news media could be either a complement to or a substitute
for bias in media reports. It could give the activist a stronger incentive to conceal informa-
24
BoththeEENandDetroitProjectcampaignswereconductedby FentonCommunications.
25
The New York Times, February 8, 2003.
26
See Appendix B.
33
tion to give the news media a greater opportunity to have moral as well as informational
influence. Moral suasion itself could be viewed as another form of media bias.
XI. Conclusions
The news media obtains information from sources as well as from its own investigative
journalism. Its news reports influence private and public politics, and this provides incen-
tives for its sources to provide information strategically. The media has discretion in its
choice and presentation of the news and thus can bias its reports. Bias could result from
the preferences of journalists or the owners of the media organization, but it could also arise
in response to the role in society the media has assumed—as a protector of democracy and
a provider of information to the public. In response, the media could report in an unbiased
manner, but it could also act to mitigate collective action problems. The collective action
problem considered here is a free-rider problem associated with an externality. By biasing
its reports the news media could mitigate both a market failure and a government failure
by reducing demand and by affecting preferences for regulation, respectively. The media’s
incentives for bias are fully taken into account by citizen consumers in both their consump-
tion and their collective choices, yet biased reports have influence because citizen consumers
can neither verify the reports nor the information provided by the media’s sources. Media
coverage then can provide incentives for sources to advocate their interests by presenting
favorable information and concealing unfavorable information.
In the model the group whose interests are aligned with the fulfillment of the media’s
role in society has an incentive to conceal unfavorable information, whereas the group
whose interests would be harmed by the public’s response to the bias has no incentive to
conceal information. An alignment between the media and certain interest groups thus
results. This alignment could, but need not, be seen as an ideological orientation of the
media through behavior that favors the causes of certain interest groups. An ideological
orientation could also result from attracting journalists with particular personal preferences
that are consistent with the alignment arising between the media’s objectives and those
of interest groups. This has implications for interest group strategies. The interest group
aligned with the media’s objectives may focus on private politics, whereas the opposing
group may be forced to focus on public politics and rely on the skepticism of the public.
34
The news media and the interest groups may also have an opportunity to influence the
preferencesof citizenconsumers throughmoral suasion. Inthe model moral suasionpertains
to the extent to which consumers take into account the effect on others of the externality
associated with their own consumption. Moral suasion in the model is a substitute for
regulation in two senses. First, it reduces the magnitude of the externality by reducing
demand. Second, it diminishes the public support for regulation. The strategic competition
among interests and the role of the news media in providing moral arguments to the public
remains a subject for future research.
The opportunity to bias news reports leaves a burden on the news media to be certain
that its bias is indeed in the interests of the public rather than in the interests of the
journalists and media owners who comprise the news organization. The institutions of
government and the collective action of citizens are intended to serve the interests of the
public, and the fundamental issue is whether the role of the news media should extend to
market and nonmarket failures that governments fail to address. Thomas Jefferson wrote,
“Were it left to me to decide whether we should have a government without newspapers
or newspapers without a government, I should not hesitate to prefer the latter.”
27
In the
presence of a government, however, should the role of the news media in society be more
limited?
27
Letter to E. Carrington, 1787.
35
Appendix A
Characterization of the Indifferent Citizen in Collective Choice
To show that some purchasers prefer regulation and others do not, note that the
difference v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
)?v
?
(s
+
,θ
+
)ispositiveif
?v
parenleftBig
(1?αs
+
)
parenleftBig
1?
n +1
nN
parenrightBig
?(α?1)η
parenrightBig
?θηN(2?α?s
+
) > 0. (A1)
The condition in (A1) is satisfied for
?v ≥
θ
+
ηN(2?α?s
+
)
(1?αs
+
)(1?
n+1
nN
)?(α?1)η,
whichissatisfiedforη small.
The condition for ?v>v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
) is identified by the difference
?v?v
o
(s
+
,θ
+
)=
n
(n +1)α?v(1?αs
+
)
bracketleftBig
?v(1?αs
+
)
parenleftBig
α?v?θ
+
N
parenleftBig
1+η?
n +1
nN
parenrightBigparenrightBig
+(θ
+
)
2
N
2
η(2?α?s
+
)
bracketrightBig
.
(A2)
The term in brackets is assumed to be positive.
Appendix B
Subscribers and Media Pricing
A. The Subscribers
The subscription decision must be made prior to any report by the media, so the
subscribers are those who expect to benefit from the reports by enough to bear the cost.
That cost is the difference between the price charged by the media and the entertainment
value of its reports.
To identify the subscribers, consider those consumers who would gain from the reports
provided by the media. The news media can make three generic reports r ∈{θ
L
,θ
H
,
?
θ},
where
?
θ ∈ (θ
L
,θ
H
) is the report of the media in the event that neither the industry nor
the activist has presented hard information nor has an investigation by the media been
successful. As demonstrated in Section VI.C, the report
?
θ leads to beliefs
ˉ
θ
o
in (14). The
citizens who purchase corresponding to the three reports are identified based on the cutoffs
v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
),v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)andv
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
), respectively, where, as identified in Section VII,
ˉ
θ
j
is the
36
posterior mean given a report r = θ
j
,j = L,H,ands
+
= 0 corresponds to the posterior
mean
ˉ
θ
o
. The cutoffs can be shown to be ordered as v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
)<v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ)<v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
), where
v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ) is the cutoff based on the prior mean
ˉ
θ in the absence of any media report. Also,
v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
)<v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)<v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
), but v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)couldbegreaterorlessthanv
?
(0,
ˉ
θ). To reduce
the number of cases considered, only that in which v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)<v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ)isanalyzedhere.This
condition is satisfied in the equilibrium.
A citizen’s subscription decision depends on her expectations about the reports she
might receive from the media. Those expectations are necessarily formed prior to sub-
scribing and are assumed to be rational in the sense that they are consistent with the
equilibrium strategies of the activist, firms, and media. The expectations are denoted
by ψ =(ψ
L
,ψ
H
,1 ? ψ
L
? ψ
H
), where ψ
i
is the probability of r = θ
i
,i = L,H.Those
expectations are identified in Section C of this Appendix.
Those consumers with v ∈ [v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
),v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)] benefit from the news report r = θ
L
,
since they will purchase, whereas based on prior information or reports r = θ
H
or r =
ˉ
θ
o
they would not. Each consumer is assumed to understand the subscription strategies of
other citizens and anticipates the collective decision. A consumer’s gain thus is only due to
the change in her consumption strategy. That gain is v?
1
n+1
?v?
n
n+1
η
ˉ
θ
L
N. The expected
gain G
L
is
G
L
= ψ
L
parenleftBig
v ?
1
n +1
?v ?
n
n +1
η
ˉ
θ
L
N
parenrightBig
= ψ
L
(v ?v
?
(0,θ
L
)), if v ∈ [v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
),v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)].
(B1)
Similarly, a consumer with v ∈ (v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ),v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)] gains when the report is r = θ
H
,
since in that event she will not purchase, whereas she would have purchased based on prior
information as well as when r = θ
L
or r =
ˉ
θ
o
. The expected gain G
H
is
G
H
= ψ
H
parenleftBig
n
n +1
(1?s)
ˉ
θ
H
ηN ?(1?αs)
parenleftBig
v?
1
n +1
?v
parenrightBigparenrightBig
= ψ
H
(1?αs)(v ?v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)), if v ∈ (v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ),v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)].
(B2)
Aconsumerwithv ∈ [v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
),v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ)] gains both if r = θ
L
or r =
ˉ
θ
o
,inwhichcases
she will purchase whereas she would not have purchased based on prior information. The
37
corresponding expected gain G(
ˉ
θ
o
)is
G(
ˉ
θ
o
)=ψ
L
parenleftBig
v ?
1
n +1
?v ?
n
n +1
η
ˉ
θ
L
N
parenrightBig
+(1?ψ
L
?ψ
H
)
parenleftBig
v ?
1
n +1
?v ?
n
n +1
ˉ
θ
o
ηN
parenrightBig
,
(B3)
where s
+
= 0 is assumed to correspond to
ˉ
θ
o
.
The difference ?G in the gains G
L
and G(
ˉ
θ
o
)in(B2) and (B3) for valuations v
L
∈
(v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
),v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
)] and v ∈ [v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
o
),v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ)], respectively, are
?G = G(
ˉ
θ
o
)?G
L
=(1?ψ
H
?ψ
L
)
parenleftBig
v ?
1
n +1
?v ?
n
n +1
ˉ
θ
o
ηN
parenrightBig
+ ψ
L
(v ?v
L
) > 0,
since v
L
<v. Consequently, the gains to consumers with valuations closer to the prior mean
are greater than the gains to consumers with lower valuations. This means that as the
media raises the price for a subscription the consumers who decide not to purchase are
those with the more extreme valuations, as identified next.
B. The Media’s Pricing
The media is assumed to charge a price k for a subscription. A subscription could also
have an entertainment value e≥0, in which case the net price is k ?e.Ifthenewsreports
are provided at a price of zero as in the case of television and radio broadcasts, k could
be interpreted as advertising revenue per subscriber. From the consumer’s perspective k
then represents the cost of enduring the advertising that is interspersed with the news
reports. If k>e, the number of subscribers S(k ?e) includes those citizen consumers with
v ∈ [v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
),v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)]whohavegainsofatleastk ?e, as illustrated in Figure 4. Using
(B1) and (B2) the number of subscribers are
S(k ?e)=
N
?v
parenleftBig
v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)?
k ?e
ψ
H
(1?αs)
?
parenleftBig
v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
)+
k ?e
ψ
L
parenrightBigparenrightBig
=
nηN
2
(n +1)?v
parenleftBig
ˉ
θ
H
(1?s)
1?αs
?
ˉ
θ
L
?
(n +1)(k?e)
ηnN
parenleftBig
ψ
L
+ ψ
H
(1?αs)
ψ
H
ψ
L
(1?αs)
parenrightBigparenrightBig
.
(B4)
As expected, the number of subscribers is increasing in e.
The profit pi
M
of the news media is
pi
M
= kS(k?e),
38
where the production cost is assumed to be zero to simplify the model. The profit depends
on the public’s beliefs about θ and not on the media’s beliefs. The profit-maximizing price
k
?
is
28
k
?
=
ηnNψ
H
ψ
L
(
ˉ
θ
H
(1?s)?
ˉ
θ
L
(1?αs))
2(n +1)(ψ
L
+ ψ
H
(1?αs))
+
e
2
, (B5)
which is strictly increasing in ψ
H
and ψ
L
. The profit pi
?
M
is
pi
?
M
=
N
?v
parenleftBig
ψ
H
(1?αs)+ψ
L
ψ
L
ψ
H
(1?αs)
parenrightBig
k
?2
. (B6)
The media’s profit is strictly increasing in ψ
H
and ψ
L
, so profit is greater the more
likely are the extreme reports r = θ
L
and r = θ
H
. This results because the set of subscribers
is greater the higher is the probability that a consumer will alter her private decision as
a result of the news report. The news media’s report is made ex post taking the set of
subscribers as fixed, and the more extreme expectations those reports support, the greater
are ex ante profits. The media cannot commit ex ante to its reporting strategy, but instead
it benefits because citizens expect that their consumption decisions are likely to be changed
by the news report.
The price and profit of the media are increasing in the stringency s of regulation
if α≤
ˉ
θ
H
ˉ
θ
L
. The media’s price and the profit are also increasing in the competitiveness of
the industry producing the product, since the lower price in a more competitive industry
increases the number of potential subscribers (v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)?v
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
))
N
?v
who could gain from
the news report. The profit in (B6) is also increasing in e, so from a profit perspective the
media has an incentive to make its stories entertaining. This both increases the number of
subscribers and allows a higher price to be charged. The entertainment dimension of its
stories is not incorporated into the model but instead is taken as a fixed characteristic of
any news report.
28
This is optimal provided that
e <
ηnNψ
L
ψ
H
(
ˉ
θ
H
(1?s)?
ˉ
θ
L
(1?αs))
2(n +1)(ψ
L
+ ψ
H
(1?αs))
,
which will be assumed to be satisfied. If this condition is not satisfied, it is optimal to price
at k = e in which case all citizen consumers subscribe. The profit is then pi
e
= e
N
?v
.This
profit is assumed to be less than that in (B6).
39
The profit is also increasing in η, so the more citizen consumers take into account the
externality associated with their consumption the greater is the media’s profit. This results
because the media increases its price as η increases, since an increase in η shifts upward
the media’s demand function.
29
The net effect on the number of subscribers cannot be
determined analytically, but for high η more citizens subscribe the greater is η.
C. Rational Expectations of the Public
The public has been assumed to form rational expectations (ψ
L
,ψ
H
,1?ψ
L
?ψ
H
)about
the possible reports r ∈{θ
L
,θ
H
,
ˉ
θ
o
}. In equilibrium the report r =
ˉ
θ
o
is never observed,
so ψ
L
+ ψ
H
=1. The probability ψ
H
is given in (29). The probability ψ
H
is increasing
in the probability that the activist conceals unfavorable information and decreasing in the
probability that the media investigates.
29
The demand function shifts upwards because although v
?
(s,
ˉ
θ
H
)andv
?
(0,
ˉ
θ
L
)both
are increasing in η, the increase is greater the greater is the posterior mean.
40
References
American Association of Newspaper Editors. 1999. Examining our Credibility: Examining
Credibility, Explaining Ourselves. Reston, Va.
Anderson, Simon P. and Stephen Coate. 2001. “Market Provision of Public Goods: The
Case of Broadcasting.” Working paper, University of Virginia.
Baron, David P. 2002. “Private Politics and Private Policies: A Theory of Boycotts.”
Working paper, Stanford University.
Baron, David P. 2003a. Business and Its Environment, 4th ed. Upper Saddle River, NJ:
Prentice Hall.
Baron, DavidP. 2003b. “PrivatePolitics.” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy.
12 (Spring): 31-66.
Besley, Timothy and Robin Burgess. 2002. “The Political Economy of Government Re-
sponsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 117:
1415-1451.
Besley, Timothy, Robin Burgess, and Andrea Prat. 2002. “Mass Media and Political
Accountability.” in The Right to Know: Institutions and the Media, Roumeen Islam,
ed. New York: World Bank, forthcoming.
Besley, Timothy and Andrea Pratt. 2001. “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Cap-
ture and Government Accountability.” Working paper, London School of Economics.
Bovitz, Gregory L., Druckman, James N., and Arthur Lupia. 2002. “When Can a News
Organization Lead Public Opinion? Ideology versus Market Forces in Decisions to
Make News.” Public Choice,forthcoming.
Dewatripoint, Mathias and Jean Tirole. 1999. “Advocates.” Journal of Political Economy.
107: 1-39.
Dukes, Anthony and Esther Gal-Or. 2001. “Minimum Differentiation in Commercial Media
Markets.” Working paper, Carnegie-Mellon University.
Dyck, Alexanderand Luigi Zingales. 2002. “The Corporate Governance Role of the Media.”
Working paper, Harvard Business School.
Erfle, Stephen and Henry McMillan. 1990. “Media, Political Pressure, and the Firm:
The Case of Petroleum Pricing in the Late 1970s.” Quarterly Journal of Economics.
41
115-134.
Friedman, Monroe. 1999. Consumer Boycotts.NewYork:Routledge.
Goldberg, Bernard. 2002. Bias: A CBS Insider Exposes How the News Media Distort the
News. Washington, DC; Regnery Publishing.
Graber, Doris A., ed. 2000. Media Power in Politics. Washington, DC; CQ Press.
Groseclose, Tim and James M. Snyder. 1996. “Buying Supermajorities,” American Politi-
cal Science Review, 90 (June): 303-315.
Hamilton, James T. 1996. “Private Interests in “Public Interest” Programming: An Eco-
nomic Assessment of Broadcaster Incentives.” Duke Law Journal. 45:1177-1192.
Hansen, Claus and Soren Kyhl. 2001. “Pay-per-view Broadcasting of Outstanding Events:
Consequences of a Ban.” International Journal of Industrial Organization. 19: 589-
609.
Krehbiel, Keith. 1998. Pivotal Politics: A Theory of Pivotal Politics.Chicago:University
of Chicago Press.
Krehbiel, Keith. 1999. “Pivotal Politics: A Refinement of Nonmarket Analysis for Voting
Institutions.” Business and Politics,1:63-81.
Mullainathan, Sendhil and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “Media Bias.” Working paper, NBER.
Noam, Eli M., ed. 1985. Video Media Competition: Regulation, Economics, and Technol-
ogy. New York; Columbia University Press.
Noam, Eli M. 1987. “A public and private-choice model of broadcasting.” Public Choice.
55: 163-187.
Owen, Bruce and Steven Wildman. 1992. Video Economics. Cambridge, MA; Harvard
University Press.
Patterson, Thomas E. and Wolfgang Donsbach. 1996. “News Decisions: Journalists as
Partisan Actors.” Political Communication. 13:453-68.
Spence, Michael and Bruce Owen. 1977. “Television Programming, Monopolistic Compe-
tition and Welfare.” Quarterly Journal of Economics. 91: 103-126.
Stromberg, David. 2001. “Radio’s Impact on Public Spending.” Working paper, Institute
for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University.
42
Stromberg, David. 2002. “Mass Media Competition, Political Competition and Public
Policy.” Working paper, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm Uni-
versity.
43
Figure 1
The Players and the Game
consumption regulation
activistindustry
The Public
(citizen
consumers)
news
media
r news report
m
A
government
market
m
M
search search
private
politics
public
politics
price
m
F
investigative
journalism
Figure 2
Time Line
Citizen con-
sumers decide
on regulation
Firms price
and consumers
purchase
Media prices
and citizens
subscribe
Activist and
the industry
search
Activist and in-
dustry communi-
cate to media
Media
investigates
and reports
Nature
selects
state
Figure 3
Media Influence
γ v
^
vv*(0,θ
L
) v*(0,θ
o
) v*(0,θ) v*(s,θ
H
)
Figure 4
Subscribers and Media Pricing and Profits
vv*(0,θ
L
) v*(0,θ
o
) v*(0,θ) v*(s,θ
H
)
subscribers pay k*
π
M
= k*A(k*-e)
media profit