Economics 2010a
Fall 2003
Edward L. Glaeser
Lecture 2
8. Financial Markets
a. Insurance Markets
b. Moral Hazard
c. Adverse Selection with one price
contracts
d. Simple Financial
Markets—Comparative Statics
e. Option Pricing and Redundant Assets
Insurance– assume that there is some
probability ? that a negative shock Z
occurs.
?1 ? ??U?Y? ? ?U?Y ? Z?
Assume further that insurance exists at
price “p”.
In that case, individuals solve:
max
I
?1 ? ??U?Y ? pI? ? ?U?Y ? Z ? I ? pI?
This yields F.O.C.
?1 ? ??pU
?
?Y ? pI? ? ??1 ? p?U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI
U
?
?Y ? pI?
U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI?
?
?
1 ? ?
1 ? p
p
Differentiation yields:
?I
?p
?
??1???U
?
?Y?pI???1???pIU
??
?Y?pI???U
?
?Y?Z?I?pI????1?p?IU
??
?Y?Z?I?pI?
??1???p
2
U
??
?Y?pI????1?p?
2
U
??
?Y?Z?I?pI?
Wecansignthisintwoways:
(1) some assumption about concavity or
(2) looking at the effect of price coming
from perfect insurance.
Assume that there is free entry in supply
but it costs c to process each dollar of
insurance (is this reasonable?); then we
must have that pI ? ?I ? cI ? 0 for any
insurance level I,orp ? ? ? c (“arbitrarily
fair insurance”).
Using this the F.O.C becomes
U
?
?Y ? ?? ? c?I?
U
?
?Y ? Z ? ?1 ? ? ? c?I?
? 1 ?
c
?1 ? ???? ? c?
For c ? 0, U
?
?Y ? pI? ? U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI?
or I ? Z and Y ? pI ? Y ? ?I ? Y ? Z ? I ? pI.
That is, consumption/income is equal
across states.
Hence, for c ? 0, people perfectly insure
against the shock. (What if c ? 0?)
The derivative of insurance w.r.t. c or p,for
c ? 0 becomes
?I
?p
?
?U
?
?Y ? ?I?
???1 ? ??p
2
? ??1 ? p?
2
?U
??
?Y ? ?I?
?
?U
?
?Y ? ?I?
??p
2
? ? ? 2p??U
??
?Y ? ?I?
which is negative and inversely
proportional to the coefficient of absolute
risk aversion at Y ? ?I.
Alternately, go back to the denominator of
the ugly expression we had before:
??1 ? ??U
?
?Y ? pI? ? ?1 ? ??pIU
??
?Y ? pI?
??U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI? ? ??1 ? p?IU
??
?Y ? Z ? I ?
We know that p ? ? ? c ? ? or
?1 ? ??p ? ??1 ? p?
so as long as
U
??
?Y ? pI? ? U
??
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI?
we’re done– this would require what to
hold?
Alternately, as long as
U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI? ? ??1 ? p?IU
??
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI
we’re done – what would ensure that?
Now assume that the problem is to
maximize:
In that case, individuals maximize:
?1 ? ??U?Y ? pI,0? ? ?U?Y ? pI,L?
Where L indicates some sort of loss:
In this case, the first order condition is:
?1 ? ??pU
1
?Y ? pI,0? ? ?pU
1
?Y ? pI,L?
In the case that c ? 0, this implies that:
U
1
?Y ? pI,0? ? U
1
?Y ? pI,L?
What does this imply about the value of I?
What does this tell you about betting on
sports events?
How about insuring the death of child,
parent, etc.?
Moral Hazard– Self Protection
Assume in this case that ? can be changed
with effort, i.e. there exists a function ??d?
which represents lowering the probability
at a cost d.
Now the consumer maximizes w.r.t. both I
and d:
?1 ? ??d??U?Y ? pI ? d? ? ??d?U?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ?
This yields F.O.C.
?1 ? ??pU
?
?Y ? pI ? d? ? ??1 ? p?U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ?
and
?
?
?d??U?Y ? pI ? d? ? U?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ? d?? ?
?1 ? ??U
?
?Y ? pI ? d? ? ?U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ? d??
If perfect insurance is available, what does
this imply about the level
of c?
This is moral hazard– because of the
availability of insurance, the
only equilibrium has far too little self
protection.
How can we construct a more efficient
contract that still leaves zero profits for the
insurer?
Cap the insurance payout at I, and then
maximize over I allowing p to equal ??d?I??
??1 ? ??pU
?
?Y ? pI ? d? ? ??1 ? p?U?Y ? Z ? I ?
?
?d
?I
??
?
?d??U?Y ? pI ? d? ? U?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ? d?? ?
?1 ? ??U?Y ? pI ? d? ? ?U?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ? d???
?d
?I
?1 ? ?????
?
?d?I?U
?
?Y ? pI ? d? ?
?d
?I
????
?
?d?I?U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ? d?
At the point where this is equal to zero,
you have an optimal
insurance cap.
Using the first order condition for
self-protection, this reduces to:
U
?
?Y ? pI ? d? ? U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ? pI ? d? ?
?
?d
?I
?
?
?d?I?
1
?
U
?
?Y ? pI ? d? ?
1
1??
U
?
?Y ? Z ? I ?
As long as
?d
?I
? 0 (self-protection declines
with insurance) then we should expect to
see some limits on the completeness of
insurance.
These will in turn be a function of the
degree to which self-protection matters
and the concavity of the utility function.
Why might this solution break down?
Adverse Selection– No asymmetric
information, but a fixed price.
Now assume a distribution of people with
different values of ?.
Characterized by a density g??? which is
continuous on the interval ?0,1?.
Assume any fixed price p, and assume (for
simplicity) that the only available insurance
contract perfectly insures (i.e. I ? Z).
Then everyone for whom:
U?Y ? pZ? ? ?1 ? ??U?Y? ? ?U?Y ? Z?, will
insure.
As ?1 ? ??U?Y? ? ?U?Y ? Z? is monotonically
decreasing in ?, and as
U?Y? ? U?Y ? pZ? ? U?Y ? Z? for any
positive Z,p
there exists a marginal consumer, denoted
with ?
?
for whom
U?Y ? pZ? ? ?1 ? ?
?
?U?Y? ? ?
?
U?Y ? Z?
So everyone with more risk than that takes
the insurance, and everyone with less risk
does not.
This is adverse selection.
To close the model, we need to
incorporate supply.
Again assume zero profits, which in this
case means that:
?
???
?
1
g????? ? p?Zd? ? 0
or p ?
?
???
?
1
g????d?
?
???
?
1
g???d?
Will there be an insurance market at all?
We know that one equilibrium sets p ? 1.
Does there exist another equilibrium?
This requires the existence of a ?
?
? 1 at
which:
U Y ?
?
???
?
1
g????d?
?
???
?
1
g???d?
Z ? ?1 ? ?
?
?U?Y? ? ?
?
U
To build intuition, take a Taylor series
expansion for U?.? around Y, and use the
notation
?
? ?
?
???
?
1
g????d?
?
???
?
1
g???d?
or
U?Y? ? U?Y ?
?
?Z? ?
?
?ZU
?
?Y ?
?
?Z? ?
1
2
?
?
2
Z
2
U
??
?Y ?
?
?Z?
U?Y ? Z? ? U?Y ?
?
?Z? ? ?1 ?
?
??ZU
?
?Y ?
?
?Z? ?
1
2
?1 ?
?
??
2
Z
2
U
??
?Y ?
?
?Z?
In which case, the equation becomes:
0 ? ?
?
? ? ??ZU
?
?Y ?
?
?Z? ?
1
2
?
?
?
2
? ?1 ?
?
??
2
?Z
2
U
or
?
?
? ? ?? ?
?U
??
?Y?
?
?Z?
2U
?
?Y?
?
?Z?
?1 ? 2
?
? ? 2
?
?
2
?
Does there exist a value
?
? at which this
holds?
It depends on the coefficient of absolute
risk aversion.
If this is close to zero (i.e. utility is close to
linear), this can never hold.
As the coefficient of relative risk aversion
goes to infinity almost everywhere.
In the case where g?.? is uniform on the
unit interval, we can
actually derive even clearer results. In that
case
?
? ?.5?1 ? ??
or 2
1??
1??
2
?
?U
??
?Y?
?
?Z?
U
?
?Y?
?
?Z?
You can actually solve this using the
quadratic equation.
In this case, there will generally exist some
sufficiently high level of
risk where people actually do ensure.
How would you think about solving this
problem?
We often talk about their being a
“risk-return frontier”.
We are generally interested in deriving the
relationship between
asset prices and risk characteristics.
One useful utility function for showing this
is quadratic utility
u?x? ? x ?
1
2
?x
2
We use that fact that
E?x ? E?x??
2
? E?x
2
? ? ?E?x??
2
to get
E?u?x?? ? E?x? ?
1
2
??E?x ? E?x??
2
? ?E?x??
2
?
? E?x? ?
1
2
??E?x??
2
?
1
2
?Var?x?
Of course, the problem quadratic utility is
that you need x ? 1/? to avoid utility falling
with income.
If you start with income y, and buy z units
of an asset with price one, mean return
1 ? r and variance ?
2
, your income have a
mean value of y ? rz and a variance of z
2
?
2
So E?u?x?? ? y ? rz ?
1
2
??y ? rz?
2
?
1
2
?z
2
?
2
In this case, the optimal choice of the risky
asset gives us:
r ? ??y ? rz? ? ?z?
2
? 0 or z ?
r??y
??
2
??r
What happens if there are multiple
independent assets?
Another way to think about it is that there is
fixed amount of risky asset to be
allocated– this implies an r,whichis
increasing in risk, concavity and
decreasing in wealth.
The pure mean-variance utility function is
exponential, i.e.
u?x? ? ?e
??x
and if x is normally distributed,
i.e.
f?x? ?
1
?
2
2?
e
??x???
2
2?
2
then
E?u?x?? ?
1
?
2
2?
??e
??x
e
??x???
2
2?
2
dx ?
1
?
2
2?
??e
?2?
2
?x??x??
2?
2
E?u?x?? ?
1
?
2
2?
??e
?
2
?
2
?2??
2
?? x????
2
?
2
2?
2
dx ?
?e
????
?
2
?
2
2
1
?
2
2?
?e
? x?????
2
??
2
2?
2
dx
But
1
?
2
2?
?e
? x?????
2
??
2
2?
2
dx ? 1,so
E?U?x?? ? ?e
????
?
2
?
2
2
And maximizing this is just equivalent to
maximizing
? ?
?
2
?
2
Options– sometimes there are redundant
assets.
Take for example a three state world.
The numeraire asset, pays off 1 in each
state, we think of the price of this asset as
one.
Asset 1 pays off 1 dollar in state 1. The
price of this asset is p
1
Asset 2 pays off 1 dollar in state 2. The
price of this asset is p
2
Any additional asset can be priced as a
function of these two assets.
For example an asset that pays of 1 in
state 3 must cost 1 ? p
1
? p
2
An asset that pays off in states 1 ? 2
should cost p
1
? p
2
Imagine a company whose stock is worth 1
instate1,2instate2and3instate3.
The price of that company’s stock ex ante
should be
p
1
? 2p
2
? 3?1 ? p
1
? p
2
?
Now imagine that we are pricing an option
to buy the company’s stock at a price of 1.
How much should that option go for?
In state one it is worth zero.
In state 2 it is worth 1 and in state 3 it is
worth 2.
Thus the option is worth p
2
? 2?1 ? p
1
? p
2
?
Imagine the stock gets riskier and pays
zeroinstate1and4instate3.
In this case, the option is worth
p
2
? 3?1 ? p
1
? p
2
?
This suggests that option prices (or at least
the gap between option prices and stock
prices) are increasing in the amount of
risk.
To get this point, consider a risk-neutral
investor considering an option to buy a
stock price at one.
Imagine the the stock price is uniformly
distributed on the interval ?1 ? a,1? a?.
Then the expected value of the option is
a/4, which is increasing in risk as
measured by a.
More generally, consider a continuous
state space, indexed by x, and assume
that assets span so that there exists a
price for each state of p?x?.
A stock has value x in each state
I can always define the states so that this
is true.
Consider the option to buy a stock at price
c
The price of that option will be
?
x?c
p?x??x ? c?dF?x?
As the option is a concave function– mean
preserving spreads will increase the value
of the option.