Economics 2010a
Fall 2003
Edward L. Glaeser
Lecture 9
9. The Producer’s Problem
a. Firms and Maximization
b. Production Functions
c. Supply and Profit Functions
d. Cost Functions
e. Duality and Producers
f. Application: Urban Systems
1. Technology
The more tradition approach is to assume:
(1) A production correspondence, e.g.
f(K,L) or more generally f?Z?, that maps the
vector of inputs Z which cost W into a
vector of outputs, which are then sold at
prices P for total revenues Pf?Z?.
In many cases, we think of f?Z? as a
function– i.e. only one output– but is
doesn’t need to be.
We assume first that firms treat prices as
given– i.e. they are price takers– i.e. they
don’t have market power.
(2) We assume that firms maximize profits,
and that they have the option (at least in
the long run) to exit, i.e. earn zero profits.
This is of course a deeply controversial
claim.
(3) We make some assumption about the
number of firms– perhaps free entry of
identical firms, perhaps something else.
This last assumption gives us a great deal
of power– this is the equilibrium
assumption in action.
Together, profit maximization and free
entry of identical firms gives us the
following two sets of conditions (assuming
that the production function is continuously
differentiable and concave).
P
?f?Z?
?Z
i
? W
i
for each input marginal revenue equals
price.
And given these first order conditions:
Pf?Z? ? W ? Z ? 0
These two, especially, when combined
with demand give you implications about
prices.
Now back to the MWG set theoretic
approach.
A production plan is a vector y ? ?
L
.
This includes both inputs and outputs, and
an input is a negative element in this
vector.
An output is a positive element in this
vector.
Total profits are p ? y
The set of all production plans is Y,which
is analogous to X, in the consumer
chapters.
We generally assume that 0 ? Y , so that
firms can shut down.
Generally, we assume that Y is
(1) nonempty (even beyond including 0)
(2) closed, i.e. includes its limit points.
(3) no free lunch– there is no vector y ? Y
where y
l
? 0, for all l and y
k
? 0 for at least
one factor l?k.
(4) free disposal– if a vector
?y
1
,..y
k
,..y
L
? ? Y where y
k
? 0, for then all
other vectors ?y
1
,..x
k
,..y
L
? ? Y where
x
k
? y
k
(you can always get rid of something).
(5) irreversibility: if y ? Y then ?y ? Y
These properties are more particular:
(6) Nonincreasing returns to scale. If
y ? Y, then ?y ? Y for all ? ? ?0,1? –you
can always scale down.
(7) Nondecreasing returns to scale. If
y ? Y, then ?y ? Y for all ? ? 1– you can
always scale up.
(8) Constant returns to scale If y ? Y, then
?y ? Y for all ? ? 0– you can always scale
up or down.
(9) Additivity (also free entry) if y ? Y and
y
?
? Y then y ? y
?
? Y
(10) Convexity if y ? Y and y
?
? Y then
?y ? ?1 ? ??y
?
? Y for all ? ? ?0,1?
(11) Y is a convex conde. If for any
y,y
?
? Y and ? ? 0, ? ? 0, ?y ? ?y
?
? Y
MWG Proposition 5.B.1: The production
set Y is additive and satisfies the
nonincreasing returns condition if and only
if it is a convex cone.
If it is a convex cone– then the
nonincreasing returns condition and
additivity immediately follow.
Let k ? Max??,?? where k is an integer,
then ky,ky
?
? Y by additivity.
Also using nonincreasing returns to scale
?
k
ky ? Y and
?
k
ky
?
? Y and we’re done.
The profit maximization problem is to
maximize p ? y subject to y ? Y
This yields a supply correspondence y?p?
And a profit function ??p? ? p ? y?p?
Properties of the profit function MWG
Proposition 5.C.1:
Suppose that ??.? is the profit function of
the production set Y, and that y?.? is the
associated supply correspondence.
Assume also that Y is closed and satisfies
the free disposal property. Then:
(1) ??.? is homogeneous of degree one.
(2) ??.? is convex
(3) y(.) is homogeneous of deree zero
(4) If Y is strictly convex, then y(.) is single
valued.
(5) If y(.) is single valued then ??.? is
differentiable and ???p? ? y?p?
(6) If y(.) is differentiable then
Dy?p? ? D
2
??p? is a symmetric and
positive semidefinite matrix with Dy?p?p ? 0
Homogeneity of degree one in prices
occurs because the vector y that
maximizes py subject to any constraint is
the same vector that maximizes ?py
subject to the same constraint for any
positive ?. This also gives us homogeneity
of degree zero for the supply
correspondence.
Convexity–
???p ? ?1 ? ??p
?
? ? ???p? ? ?1 ? ????p
?
? for
? ? ?0,1? .
Let p
??
? ?p ? ?1 ? ??p
?
and have y,y
?
and y
??
denote the optimal production vectors at
the three price levels.
Then we know that
???p ? ?1 ? ??p
?
? ? ?py
??
? ?1 ? ??p
?
y
??
But py
??
? py and p
?
y
??
? p
?
y
?
and we’re
done.
Cost minimization– now assume a fixed
vector of outputs and a production function
f(Z).
The cost minimization problem is to
minimize W ? Z subject to f?Z? ? Q for some
fixed level Q.
In principle, this quantity constraint could
handle a lot of different outputs, but we will
certainly focus on the idea of a single
output.
The correspondence Z?W,Q? is the input
demand that satisfies cost minimization.
The cost function C?W,Q? ? W ? Z?W,Q?
Properties of the Cost Function MWG
Proposition 5.C.2:
Suppose that C(W,Q) is the cost function
of a single output technology Y, with
production function F(.) and that Z(W,Q) is
the associated conditional factor demand
correspondence. Assume also that Y is
closed and satisfies the free disposal
property. Then:
(1) C(.) is homogeneous of degree one in
W
(2) C(.) is nondecreasing in Q
(3) C(.) is a concave function of W
(4) C(.) is homogeneous of degree zero in
W.
(5) If Z?W,Q? consists of a single point at
W, then C?W,Q? is differentiable at W and
?
W
C?W,Q? ? Z?W,Q? (shephard’s lemma)
(6) If Z?W,Q? is differentiable at W, then
D
W
Z?W,Q? ? D
W
2
C?W,Q? is a symmetric
and negative semidefinite matrix with
D
W
Z?W,Q?W ? 0
(7) If F(.) is homogeneous of degree one
then Z(.) and C(.) are also homogeneous
of degree one.
(8) If F(.) is concave, then C(.) is a convex
function of Q.
The fact that costs satisfty homogeneity of
degree one in input prices follows from the
fact that if we scale all prices up by the
same constant, the solution to the
minimization problem is unchanged.
This also gives us that input demand is
homogeneous of degree zero.
Convexity in costs is directly parallel to
concavity of the profit function.
C??W ? ?1 ? ??W
?
,Q? ?
?C?W,Q? ? ?1 ? ??C?W
?
,Q? ,for? ? ?0,1? .
Let W
??
? ?W ? ?1 ? ??W
?
and have Z,Z
?
and Z
??
denote the input vectors at the
three price levels.
Then we know that
C??W ? ?1 ? ??W
?
,Q? ? ?WZ
??
? ?1 ? ??W
?
Z
??
But WZ
??
? WZ and W
?
Z
??
? W
?
Z
?
and we’re
done.
The nondecreasing property follows from
free disposal.
Lastly Shephard’s lemma follows from the
fact that:
C?W,Q? ? WZ ? ??Q ? F?Z??
which has first order conditions:
W
j
? ?
?F?Z?
?Z
i
Differentiate this with respect to any W
i
and we get
?C
?W
i
? Z
i
? ?W
j
?Z
j
?W
i
? ??
?F?Z?
?Z
i
?Z
j
?W
i
But all the terms beyond Z
i
just drop out
(this is the envelope theorem in action).
A few production functions to know:
Leontief: Y ? Min??
1
Z
1
,...?
L
Z
L
?
Linear Y ? ??
i
Z
i
Cobb-Douglas Y ?
?
Z
i
?
i
This is increasing returns if ??
i
? 1,
decreasing returns if ??
i
? 1 and
constant returns if ??
i
? 1
Remember you can’t just take logs in this
case, but you do know that: ?
i
Y ? W
i
Z
i
for
all i.
This gives you the fact that constant
returns technologies are the only ones that
yield zero profits.
Constant elasticity of substitution:
???
i
Z
i
?
?
1/?
This yields factor demand of
Y ?
W
i
?
i
1
1??
Z
i
, for all i.
Systems of cities– supply and demand
together: Back to compensating
differentials.
Define consumer utility over non-housing
consumption, housing prices and
amenities and assume that homes are
homogeneous.
This means that utility is U?W ? C,A?,
where C is housing prices.
Then indifference across space gives us
that
U?W ? C,A? ? U
Or if we assume that that communities fall
along a continuum:
dW ? dC ?
U
1
U
2
dA
The increase in wages minus prices must
exactly offset the increase in amenities.
This is a very famous condition that has
been the basis for most of urban
economics.
But this is only part of the story– there also
must be a equilibrium in the product
market.
Let’s assume that profits equal Pf(L, Z)-WL
And assume that free entry pins these
down to zero.
Then we need to have across space:
dPf(L,Z)?P
?f
?Z
dZ ? dW ? L ? 0
Change in prices times quantity plus price
times change in productivity minus change
in wage must equal zero.
If prices are constant across space (the
traded goods assumption– if not they
would have to show up in the consumers
side as well–you can do this)– we might as
well assume P?1 and then we have
dW ?
1
L
?f
?Z
Thus changes in prices over space must
reflect both sides of the market– changes
in productivity and changes in either
amenities or housing costs.
Now we have
1
L
?f
?Z
?
U
1
U
2
dA ? dC
Changes in housing costs across space
add together change in consumer
amenities and producer amenities.
Now to close the model, we need to think
about equilibrium in the housing supply
sector.
Perhaps homebuilders face a technology
G(Q,D) which is their costs per unit built as
a function of local characteristics including
density, and let g(Q,D) refer to the
derivative of this with respect to quantity.
Then we have C?g(Q,D) and
dC ?
?g
?Q
dQ ?
?g
?Q
dD
Or
1
L
?f
?Z
?
U
1
U
2
dA ?
?g
?Q
dD ?
?g
?Q
dQ
Changes in population across space add
together these three different forms of local
amenities.
If for example, D didn’t change over space,
then this tells you that the population
response to production amenities depends
completely on the supply elasticity of
housing.