User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 405:26545#/eps at 100%*26545* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
When a government spends more than it collects in taxes, it borrows from the
private sector to finance the budget deficit.The accumulation of past borrowing
is the government debt. Debate about the appropriate amount of government
debt in the United States is as old as the country itself.Alexander Hamilton be-
lieved that “a national debt, if it is not excessive, will be to us a national blessing,”
whereas James Madison argued that “a public debt is a public curse.” Indeed, the
location of the nation’s capital was chosen as part of a deal in which the federal
government assumed the Revolutionary War debts of the states: because the
Northern states had larger outstanding debts, the capital was located in the
South.
Although attention to the government debt has waxed and waned over the
years, it was especially intense during the last two decades of the twentieth cen-
tury. Beginning in the early 1980s, the U.S. federal government began running
large budget deficits—in part because of increased spending and in part because
of reduced taxes. As a result, the government debt expressed as a percentage of
GDP roughly doubled from 26 percent in 1980 to 50 percent in 1995. By the
late 1990s, the budget deficit had come under control and had even turned into
a budget surplus. Policymakers then turned to the question of how rapidly the
debt should be paid off.
The large increase in government debt from 1980 to 1995 is without prece-
dent in U.S. history. Government debt most often rises in periods of war or de-
pression, but the United States experienced neither during this time. Not
surprisingly, the episode sparked a renewed interest among economists and poli-
cymakers in the economic effects of government debt. Some view the large bud-
get deficits of the 1980s and 1990s as the worst mistake of economic policy since
the Great Depression, whereas others think that the deficits matter very little.
This chapter considers various facets of this debate.
We begin by looking at the numbers. Section 15-1 examines the size of the
U.S. government debt, comparing it to the debt of other countries and to the
debt that the United States has had during its own past. It also takes a brief look
at what the future may hold. Section 15-2 discusses why measuring changes in
| 405
15
Government Debt
CHAPTER
Blessed are the young, for they shall inherit the national debt.
— Herbert Hoover
FIFTEEN
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 406:28036#/eps at 100%*28036* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
government indebtedness is not as straightforward as it might seem. Indeed, some
economists argue that traditional measures are so misleading that they should be
completely ignored.
We then look at how government debt affects the economy. Section 15-3 de-
scribes the traditional view of government debt, according to which government
borrowing reduces national saving and crowds out capital accumulation. This
view is held by most economists and has been implicit in the discussion of fiscal
policy throughout this book. Section 15-4 discusses an alternative view, called
Ricardian equivalence, which is held by a small but influential minority of econo-
mists.According to the Ricardian view, government debt does not influence na-
tional saving and capital accumulation. As we will see, the debate between the
traditional and Ricardian views of government debt arises from disagreements
over how consumers respond to the government’s debt policy.
Section 15-5 then looks at other facets of the debate over government debt. It
begins by discussing whether the government should try to always balance its
budget and, if not, when a budget deficit or surplus is desirable. It also examines
the effects of government debt on monetary policy, the political process, and the
role of a country in the world economy.
15-1 The Size of the Government Debt
Let’s begin by putting the government debt in perspective. In 2001, the debt
of the U.S. federal government was $3.2 trillion. If we divide this number by
276 million, the number of people in the United States, we find that each per-
son’s share of the government debt was about $11,600. Obviously, this is not a
trivial number—few people sneeze at $11,600.Yet if we compare this debt to
406 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
Country Government Debt as Country Government Debt as
a Percentage of GDP a Percentage of GDP
Japan 119 Ireland 54
Italy 108 Spain 53
Belgium 105 Finland 51
Canada 101 Sweden 49
Greece 100 Germany 46
Denmark 67 Austria 40
United Kingdom 64 Netherlands 27
United States 62 Australia 26
France 58 Norway 24
Portugal 55
Source: OECD Economic Outlook. Figures are based on estimates of gross government debt and GDP for 2001.
How Indebted Are the World’s Governments?
table 15-1
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 407:28037#/eps at 100%*28037* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
the roughly $1 million a typical person will earn over his or her working life,
the government debt does not look like the catastrophe it is sometimes made
out to be.
One way to judge the size of a government’s debt is to compare it to the
amount of debt other countries have accumulated.Table 15-1 shows the amount
of government debt for 19 major countries expressed as a percentage of each
country’s GDP. On the top of the list are the heavily indebted countries of Japan
and Italy, which have accumulated a debt that exceeds annual GDP. At the bot-
tom are Norway and Australia, which have accumulated relatively small debts.
The United States is in the middle of the pack. By international standards, the
U.S. government is neither especially profligate nor especially frugal.
Over the course of U.S. history, the indebtedness of the federal government
has varied substantially. Figure 15-1 shows the ratio of the federal debt to GDP
since 1791.The government debt, relative to the size of the economy, varies from
close to zero in the 1830s to a maximum of 107 percent of GDP in 1945.
Historically, the primary cause of increases in the government debt is war.
The debt–GDP ratio rises sharply during major wars and falls slowly during
peacetime. Many economists think that this historical pattern is the appropriate
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 407
figure 15-1
Year
Debt–GDP
ratio
Revolutionary
War
Civil
War
World War I
World War II
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
1791 1811 1831 1851 1871 1891 1911 1931 1951 1971 1991 2001
The Ratio of Government Debt to GDP Since 1790 The U.S. federal government debt
held by the public, relative to the size of the U.S. economy, rises sharply during wars
and declines slowly during peacetime. The exception is the period since 1980, when
the debt–GDP ratio rose without the occurrence of a major military conflict.
Source: U.S. Department of Treasury, U.S. Department of Commerce, and T.S. Berry, “Production and
Population Since 1789,” Bostwick Paper No. 6, Richmond, 1988.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 408:28038#/eps at 100%*28038* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
way to run fiscal policy. As we discuss more fully later in this chapter, deficit
financing of wars appears optimal for reasons of both tax smoothing and gen-
erational equity. One instance of a large increase in government debt in
peacetime occurred during the 1980s and early 1990s, when the federal gov-
ernment ran substantial budget deficits. Many economists have criticized this
increase in government debt as imposing a burden on future generations
without justification.
During the middle of the 1990s, the U.S. federal government started to get its
budget deficit under control. A combination of tax hikes, spending cuts, and
rapid economic growth caused the ratio of debt to GDP to stabilize and then de-
cline. Recent experience has tempted some observers to think that exploding
government debt is a thing of the past. But as the next case study suggests, the
worst may be yet to come.
408 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
CASE STUDY
The Fiscal Future: Good News and Bad News
What does the future hold for fiscal policymakers? Economic forecasting is far
from precise, and it is easy to be cynical about economic predictions. But good
policy cannot be made if policymakers only look backwards.As a result, econo-
mists in the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and other government agen-
cies are always trying to look ahead to see what problems and opportunities are
likely to develop.
When George W. Bush moved into the White House in 2001, the fiscal pic-
ture facing the U.S. government was mixed. In particular, it depended on how far
one looked ahead.
Over a ten- or twenty-year horizon, the picture looked good.The U.S. federal
government was running a large budget surplus. As a percentage of GDP, the
projected surplus for 2001 was the largest since 1948. Moreover, the surplus was
expected to grow even larger over time.The surplus was large enough so that,
without any policy changes, the government debt would be paid off by 2008.
These surpluses arose from various sources.The elder George Bush had signed
a tax increase in 1990, and Bill Clinton had signed another in 1993. Because of
these tax hikes, federal tax revenue as a percentage of GDP reached its highest
level since World War II.Then, in the late 1990s, productivity accelerated, most
likely because of advances in information technology. The high growth in in-
comes led to rising tax revenue, which pushed the federal government’s budget
from deficit to surplus.
A debate arose over how to respond to the budget surplus.The government
could use the large projected surpluses to repay debt, increase spending, cut taxes,
or some combination of these.The new Republican president George W. Bush
advocated a tax cut of $1.6 trillion over 10 years, which was about one-fourth of
the projected surpluses. Democrats in Congress argued for a smaller tax cut and
greater government spending.The end result was a compromise bill that cut taxes
by a bit less than Bush had advocated.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 409:28039#/eps at 100%*28039* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
15-2 Problems in Measurement
The government budget deficit equals government spending minus government
revenue, which in turn equals the amount of new debt the government needs to
issue to finance its operations.This definition may sound simple enough, but in
fact debates over fiscal policy sometimes arise over how the budget deficit should
be measured. Some economists believe that the deficit as currently measured is
not a good indicator of the stance of fiscal policy. That is, they believe that the
budget deficit does not accurately gauge either the impact of fiscal policy on
today’s economy or the burden being placed on future generations of taxpayers. In
this section we discuss four problems with the usual measure of the budget deficit.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 409
While the 10-year horizon looked rosy, the longer-term fiscal picture was more
troublesome.The problem was demographic.Advances in medical technology have
been increasing life expectancy, while improvements in birth-control techniques
and changing social norms have reduced the number of children people have. Be-
cause of these developments, the elderly are becoming a larger share of the popula-
tion. In 1990, there were 21 elderly for every 100 people of working age (ages 20
to 64); this figure is projected to rise to 36 by the year 2030. Such a demographic
change has profound implications for fiscal policy.About one-third of the budget
of the U.S. federal government is devoted to pensions and health care for the el-
derly. As more people become eligible for these “entitlements,” as they are some-
times called, government spending automatically rises over time, pushing the
budget toward deficit.
The magnitude of these budgetary pressures was documented in a CBO re-
port released in October 2000. According to the CBO, if no changes in fiscal
policy are enacted, the government debt as a percentage of GDP will start rising
around 2030 and reach historic highs around 2060. At that point, the govern-
ment’s budget will spiral out of control.
1
Of course, all economic forecasts need to be greeted with a bit of skepticism,
especially those that try to look ahead half a century. Shocks to the economy can
alter the government’s revenue and spending. In fact, only months after moving
into the White House, George W. Bush saw the fiscal picture start to change.
First, the economic slowdown in 2001 reduced tax revenue.Then, the terrorist
attacks in September 2001 induced an increase in government spending. Both
developments reduced the projected near-term government surpluses. As this
book was going to press, there was great uncertainty about future government
spending and the rate of technological advance—two key determinants of the
fiscal situation.
Yet one thing is clear: the elderly are making up a larger share of the popula-
tion, and this fact will shape the fiscal challenges in the decades ahead.
1
Congressional Budget Office, The Long-Term Budget Outlook, October 2000.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 410:28040#/eps at 100%*28040* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
Measurement Problem 1: Inflation
The least controversial of the measurement issues is the correction for inflation.
Almost all economists agree that the government’s indebtedness should be mea-
sured in real terms, not in nominal terms.The measured deficit should equal the
change in the government’s real debt, not the change in its nominal debt.
The budget deficit as commonly measured, however, does not correct for in-
flation.To see how large an error this induces, consider the following example.
Suppose that the real government debt is not changing; in other words, in real
terms, the budget is balanced. In this case, the nominal debt must be rising at the
rate of inflation.That is,
D
D/D =
p
,
where
p
is the inflation rate and D is the stock of government debt.This implies
D
D =
p
D.
The government would look at the change in the nominal debt
D
D and would
report a budget deficit of
p
D. Hence, most economists believe that the reported
budget deficit is overstated by the amount
p
D.
We can make the same argument in another way.The deficit is government
expenditure minus government revenue. Part of expenditure is the interest paid
on the government debt. Expenditure should include only the real interest paid
on the debt rD, not the nominal interest paid iD. Because the difference between
the nominal interest rate i and the real interest rate r is the inflation rate
p
, the
budget deficit is overstated by
p
D.
This correction for inflation can be large, especially when inflation is high,
and it can often change our evaluation of fiscal policy. For example, in 1979, the
federal government reported a budget deficit of $28 billion. Inflation was 8.6
percent, and the government debt held at the beginning of the year by the pub-
lic (excluding the Federal Reserve) was $495 billion.The deficit was therefore
overstated by
p
D = 0.086 × $495 billion
= $43 billion.
Corrected for inflation, the reported budget deficit of $28 billion turns into a
budget surplus of $15 billion! In other words, even though nominal government
debt was rising, real government debt was falling.
Measurement Problem 2: Capital Assets
Many economists believe that an accurate assessment of the government’s budget
deficit requires accounting for the government’s assets as well as its liabilities. In
particular, when measuring the government’s overall indebtedness, we should
subtract government assets from government debt.Therefore, the budget deficit
should be measured as the change in debt minus the change in assets.
410 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 411:28041#/eps at 100%*28041* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
Certainly, individuals and firms treat assets and liabilities symmetrically.When
a person borrows to buy a house, we do not say that he is running a budget
deficit. Instead, we offset the increase in assets (the house) against the increase in
debt (the mortgage) and record no change in net wealth. Perhaps we should treat
the government’s finances the same way.
A budget procedure that accounts for assets as well as liabilities is called capi-
tal budgeting, because it takes into account changes in capital. For example,
suppose that the government sells one of its office buildings or some of its land
and uses the proceeds to reduce the government debt. Under current budget
procedures, the reported deficit would be lower. Under capital budgeting, the
revenue received from the sale would not lower the deficit, because the reduc-
tion in debt would be offset by a reduction in assets. Similarly, under capital bud-
geting, government borrowing to finance the purchase of a capital good would
not raise the deficit.
The major difficulty with capital budgeting is that it is hard to decide which
government expenditures should count as capital expenditures. For example,
should the interstate highway system be counted as an asset of the government?
If so, what is its value? What about the stockpile of nuclear weapons? Should
spending on education be treated as expenditure on human capital? These diffi-
cult questions must be answered if the government is to adopt a capital budget.
Economists and policymakers disagree about whether the federal government
should use capital budgeting. (Many state governments already use it.) Oppo-
nents of capital budgeting argue that, although the system is superior in principle
to the current system, it is too difficult to implement in practice. Proponents of
capital budgeting argue that even an imperfect treatment of capital assets would
be better than ignoring them altogether.
Measurement Problem 3: Uncounted Liabilities
Some economists argue that the measured budget deficit is misleading because it
excludes some important government liabilities. For example, consider the pen-
sions of government workers.These workers provide labor services to the govern-
ment today, but part of their compensation is deferred to the future. In essence,
these workers are providing a loan to the government.Their future pension bene-
fits represent a government liability not very different from government debt.Yet
this liability is not included as part of the government debt, and the accumulation
of this liability is not included as part of the budget deficit.According to some es-
timates, this implicit liability is almost as large as the official government debt.
Similarly, consider the Social Security system. In some ways, the system is like a
pension plan. People pay some of their income into the system when young and
expect to receive benefits when old. Perhaps accumulated future Social Security
benefits should be included in the government’s liabilities. Estimates suggest that
the government’s future Social Security liabilities (less future Social Security taxes)
are more than three times the government debt as officially measured.
One might argue that Social Security liabilities are different from government
debt because the government can change the laws determining Social Security
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 411
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 412:28042#/eps at 100%*28042* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
benefits.Yet, in principle, the government could always choose not to repay all of
its debt: the government honors its debt only because it chooses to do so.
Promises to pay the holders of government debt may not be fundamentally dif-
ferent from promises to pay the future recipients of Social Security.
A particularly difficult form of government liability to measure is the contingent
liability—the liability that is due only if a specified event occurs. For example,
the government guarantees many forms of private credit, such as student loans,
mortgages for low- and moderate-income families, and deposits in banks and
savings-and-loan institutions. If the borrower repays the loan, the government
pays nothing; if the borrower defaults, the government makes the repayment.
When the government provides this guarantee, it undertakes a liability contin-
gent on the borrower’s default.Yet this contingent liability is not reflected in the
budget deficit, in part because it is not clear what dollar value to attach to it.
Measurement Problem 4: The Business Cycle
Many changes in the government’s budget deficit occur automatically in re-
sponse to a fluctuating economy. For example, when the economy goes into a
recession, incomes fall, so people pay less in personal income taxes. Profits fall, so
corporations pay less in corporate income taxes. More people become eligible
for government assistance, such as welfare and unemployment insurance, so gov-
ernment spending rises. Even without any change in the laws governing taxation
and spending, the budget deficit increases.
These automatic changes in the deficit are not errors in measurement, because
the government truly borrows more when a recession depresses tax revenue and
boosts government spending. But these changes do make it more difficult to use the
deficit to monitor changes in fiscal policy.That is, the deficit can rise or fall either
because the government has changed policy or because the economy has changed
direction. For some purposes, it would be good to know which is occurring.
To solve this problem, the government calculates a cyclically adjusted bud-
get deficit (sometimes called the full-employment budget deficit).The cyclically ad-
justed deficit is based on estimates of what government spending and tax revenue
would be if the economy were operating at its natural rate of output and em-
ployment. The cyclically adjusted deficit is a useful measure because it reflects
policy changes but not the current stage of the business cycle.
Summing Up
Economists differ in the importance they place on these measurement problems.
Some believe that the problems are so severe that the measured budget deficit is
almost meaningless. Most take these measurement problems seriously but still
view the measured budget deficit as a useful indicator of fiscal policy.
The undisputed lesson is that to evaluate fully what fiscal policy is doing, econ-
omists and policymakers must look at more than only the measured budget deficit.
And, in fact, they do.The budget documents prepared annually by the Office of
Management and Budget contain much detailed information about the govern-
ment’s finances, including data on capital expenditures and credit programs.
412 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 413:28043#/eps at 100%*28043* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
No economic statistic is perfect.Whenever we see a number reported in the
media, we need to know what it is measuring and what it is leaving out.This is
especially true for data on government debt and budget deficits.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 413
CASE STUDY
Generational Accounting
One harsh critic of current measures of the budget deficit is economist Laurence
Kotlikoff. Kotlikoff argues that the budget deficit is like the fabled emperor who
wore no clothes: everyone should plainly see the problem, but no one is willing
to admit to it. He writes,“On the conceptual level, the budget deficit is intellec-
tually bankrupt. On the practical level, there are so many official deficits that ‘bal-
anced budget’ has lost any true meaning.” He sees an “urgent need to switch
from an outdated, misleading, and fundamentally noneconomic measure of fiscal
policy, namely the budget deficit, to generational accounting.”
Generational accounting, Kotlikoff’s new way to gauge the influence of fiscal
policy, is based on the idea that a person’s economic well-being depends on his
or her lifetime income. (This idea is founded on Modigliani’s life-cycle theory of
consumer behavior, which we examine in Chapter 16.) When evaluating fiscal
policy, therefore, we should not be concerned with taxes or spending in any sin-
gle year. Instead, we should look at the taxes paid, and transfers received, by peo-
ple over their entire lives. Generational accounts measure the impact of fiscal
policy on the lifetime incomes of different generations.
Generational accounts tell a very different story than the budget deficit about
the history of U.S. fiscal policy. In the early 1980s, the U.S. government cut taxes,
beginning a long period of large budget deficits. Most commentators claim that
older generations benefited at the expense of younger generations during this
period, because the young inherited the government debt. Kotlikoff agrees that
these tax cuts raised the burden on the young, but he claims that this standard
analysis ignores the impact of many other policy changes. His generational ac-
counts show that the young were hit even harder during the 1950s, 1960s, and
1970s. During these years, the government raised Social Security benefits for the
elderly and financed the higher spending by taxing the working-age population.
This policy redistributed income away from the young, even though it did not
affect the budget deficit. During the 1980s, Social Security reforms reversed this
trend, benefiting younger generations.
Despite Kotlikoff’s advocacy, generational accounting is not likely to replace
the budget deficit.This alternative system also has flaws. For example, to calculate
the total tax burden on different generations, one needs to make assumptions
about future policy, which are open to dispute. Nonetheless, generational ac-
counting offers a useful perspective in the debate over fiscal policy.
2
2
Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Generational Accounting: Knowing Who Pays, and When, for What We Spend
(New York:The Free Press, 1992). For an appraisal of the book, see David M. Cutler, Book Review,
National Tax Journal 56 (March 1993): 61–67. See also the symposium on generational accounting
in the Winter 1994 issue of the Journal of Economic Perspectives.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 414:28044#/eps at 100%*28044* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
15-3 The Traditional View of
Government Debt
Imagine that you are an economist working for the Congressional Budget Office
(CBO).You receive a letter from the chair of the Senate Budget Committee:
Dear CBO Economist:
Congress is about to consider the president’s request to cut all taxes by 20 per-
cent. Before deciding whether to endorse the request, my committee would like
your analysis.We see little hope of reducing government spending, so the tax cut
would mean an increase in the budget deficit. How would the tax cut and budget
deficit affect the economy and the economic well-being of the country?
Sincerely,
Committee Chair
Before responding to the senator, you open your favorite economics textbook—
this one, of course—to see what the models predict for such a change in fiscal
policy.
To analyze the long-run effects of this policy change, you turn to the mod-
els in Chapters 3 through 8. The model in Chapter 3 shows that a tax cut
stimulates consumer spending and reduces national saving. The reduction in
saving raises the interest rate, which crowds out investment. The Solow
growth model introduced in Chapter 7 shows that lower investment eventu-
ally leads to a lower steady-state capital stock and a lower level of output. Be-
cause we concluded in Chapter 8 that the U.S. economy has less capital than
in the Golden Rule steady state (the steady state with maximium consump-
tion), the fall in steady-state capital means lower consumption and reduced
economic well-being.
To analyze the short-run effects of the policy change, you turn to the IS–LM
model in Chapters 10 and 11.This model shows that a tax cut stimulates con-
sumer spending, which implies an expansionary shift in the IS curve. If there is
no change in monetary policy, the shift in the IS curve leads to an expansionary
shift in the aggregate demand curve. In the short run, when prices are sticky, the
expansion in aggregate demand leads to higher output and lower unemploy-
ment. Over time, as prices adjust, the economy returns to the natural rate of out-
put, and the higher aggregate demand results in a higher price level.
To see how international trade affects your analysis, you turn to the open-
economy models in Chapters 5 and 12. The model in Chapter 5 shows that
when national saving falls, people start financing investment by borrowing from
abroad, causing a trade deficit.Although the inflow of capital from abroad lessens
the effect of the fiscal-policy change on U.S. capital accumulation, the United
States becomes indebted to foreign countries. The fiscal-policy change also
causes the dollar to appreciate, which makes foreign goods cheaper in the United
States and domestic goods more expensive abroad.The Mundell–Fleming model
in Chapter 12 shows that the appreciation of the dollar and the resulting fall in
net exports reduce the short-run expansionary impact of the fiscal change on
output and employment.
414 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 415:28045#/eps at 100%*28045* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:28 PM
With all these models in mind, you draft a response:
Dear Senator:
A tax cut financed by government borrowing would have many effects on the
economy.The immediate impact of the tax cut would be to stimulate consumer
spending. Higher consumer spending affects the economy in both the short run
and the long run.
In the short run, higher consumer spending would raise the demand for goods
and services and thus raise output and employment. Interest rates would also rise,
however, as investors competed for a smaller flow of saving. Higher interest rates
would discourage investment and would encourage capital to flow in from abroad.
The dollar would rise in value against foreign currencies, and U.S. firms would be-
come less competitive in world markets.
In the long run, the smaller national saving caused by the tax cut would mean a
smaller capital stock and a greater foreign debt.Therefore, the output of the nation
would be smaller, and a greater share of that output would be owed to foreigners.
The overall effect of the tax cut on economic well-being is hard to judge. Cur-
rent generations would benefit from higher consumption and higher employment,
although inflation would likely be higher as well. Future generations would bear
much of the burden of today’s budget deficits: they would be born into a nation
with a smaller capital stock and a larger foreign debt.
Your faithful servant,
CBO Economist
The senator replies:
Dear CBO Economist:
Thank you for your letter. It made sense to me. But yesterday my committee
heard testimony from a prominent economist who called herself a “Ricardian’’ and
who reached quite a different conclusion. She said that a tax cut by itself would not
stimulate consumer spending. She concluded that the budget deficit would there-
fore not have all the effects you listed.What’s going on here?
Sincerely,
Committee Chair
After studying the next section, you write back to the senator, explaining in de-
tail the debate over Ricardian equivalence.
15-4 The Ricardian View of Government Debt
The traditional view of government debt presumes that when the government
cuts taxes and runs a budget deficit, consumers respond to their higher after-tax
income by spending more.An alternative view, called Ricardian equivalence,
questions this presumption. According to the Ricardian view, consumers are
forward-looking and, therefore, base their spending not only on their current in-
come but also on their expected future income. As we explore more fully in
Chapter 16, the forward-looking consumer is at the heart of many modern the-
ories of consumption.The Ricardian view of government debt applies the logic
of the forward-looking consumer to analyze the effects of fiscal policy.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 415
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 416:28046#/eps at 100%*28046* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
The Basic Logic of Ricardian Equivalence
Consider the response of a forward-looking consumer to the tax cut that the Sen-
ate Budget Committee is considering.The consumer might reason as follows:
The government is cutting taxes without any plans to reduce government spend-
ing. Does this policy alter my set of opportunities? Am I richer because of this tax
cut? Should I consume more?
Maybe not.The government is financing the tax cut by running a budget deficit.
At some point in the future, the government will have to raise taxes to pay off the
debt and accumulated interest. So the policy really represents a tax cut today cou-
pled with a tax hike in the future.The tax cut merely gives me transitory income
that eventually will be taken back. I am not any better off, so I will leave my con-
sumption unchanged.
The forward-looking consumer understands that government borrowing today
means higher taxes in the future. A tax cut financed by government debt does
not reduce the tax burden; it merely reschedules it. It therefore should not en-
courage the consumer to spend more.
One can view this argument another way. Suppose that the government bor-
rows $1,000 from the typical citizen to give that citizen a $1,000 tax cut. In
essence, this policy is the same as giving the citizen a $1,000 government bond as
a gift. One side of the bond says,“The government owes you, the bondholder,
$1,000 plus interest.’’The other side says,“You, the taxpayer, owe the government
$1,000 plus interest.’’ Overall, the gift of a bond from the government to the typ-
ical citizen does not make the citizen richer or poorer, because the value of the
bond is offset by the value of the future tax liability.
The general principle is that government debt is equivalent to future taxes,
and if consumers are sufficiently forward-looking, future taxes are equivalent to
current taxes. Hence, financing the government by debt is equivalent to financ-
ing it by taxes. This view is called Ricardian equivalence after the famous
nineteenth-century economist David Ricardo, because he first noted the theo-
retical argument.
The implication of Ricardian equivalence is that a debt-financed tax cut
leaves consumption unaffected. Households save the extra disposable income to
pay the future tax liability that the tax cut implies.This increase in private saving
exactly offsets the decrease in public saving. National saving—the sum of private
and public saving—remains the same.The tax cut therefore has none of the ef-
fects that the traditional analysis predicts.
The logic of Ricardian equivalence does not mean that all changes in fiscal
policy are irrelevant. Changes in fiscal policy do influence consumer spending
if they influence present or future government purchases. For example, sup-
pose that the government cuts taxes today because it plans to reduce govern-
ment purchases in the future. If the consumer understands that this tax cut
does not require an increase in future taxes, he feels richer and raises his con-
sumption. But note that it is the reduction in government purchases, rather
than the reduction in taxes, that stimulates consumption: the announcement
416 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 417:28047#/eps at 100%*28047* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
of a future reduction in government purchases would raise consumption
today even if current taxes were unchanged, because it would imply lower
taxes at some time in the future.
Consumers and Future Taxes
The essence of the Ricardian view is that when people choose their consump-
tion, they rationally look ahead to the future taxes implied by government debt.
But how forward-looking are consumers? Defenders of the traditional view of
government debt believe that the prospect of future taxes does not have as large
an influence on current consumption as the Ricardian view assumes. Here are
some of their arguments.
3
Myopia Proponents of the Ricardian view of fiscal policy assume that people
are rational when making decisions such as choosing how much of their income
to consume and how much to save.When the government borrows to pay for
current spending, rational consumers look ahead to the future taxes required to
support this debt.Thus, the Ricardian view presumes that people have substantial
knowledge and foresight.
One possible argument for the traditional view of tax cuts is that people are
shortsighted, perhaps because they do not fully comprehend the implications of
government budget deficits. It is possible that some people follow simple and not
fully rational rules of thumb when choosing how much to save. Suppose, for ex-
ample, that a person acts on the assumption that future taxes will be the same as
current taxes.This person will fail to take account of future changes in taxes re-
quired by current government policies. A debt-financed tax cut will lead this
person to believe that his lifetime income has increased, even if it hasn’t.The tax
cut will therefore lead to higher consumption and lower national saving.
Borrowing Constraints The Ricardian view of government debt assumes that
consumers base their spending not only on current income but on their lifetime
income, which includes both current and expected future income.According to
the Ricardian view, a debt-financed tax cut increases current income, but it does
not alter lifetime income or consumption. Advocates of the traditional view of
government debt argue that current income is more important than lifetime in-
come for those consumers who face binding borrowing constraints. A borrowing
constraint is a limit on how much an individual can borrow from banks or other
finanical institutions.
A person who would like to consume more than his current income—per-
haps because he expects higher income in the future—has to do so by borrow-
ing. If he cannot borrow to finance current consumption, or can borrow only a
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 417
3
For a survey of the debate over Ricardian equivalence, see Douglas Bernheim, “Ricardian
Equivalence: An Evaluation of Theory and Evidence,’’ NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1987):
263–303. See also the symposium on budget deficits in the Spring 1989 issue of the Journal of Eco-
nomic Perspectives.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 418:28048#/eps at 100%*28048* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
limited amount, his current income determines his spending, regardless of what
his lifetime income might be. In this case, a debt-financed tax cut raises current
income and thus consumption, even though future income is lower. In essence,
when the government cuts current taxes and raises future taxes, it is giving tax-
payers a loan. For a person who wanted to obtain a loan but was unable to, the
tax cut expands his opportunities and stimulates consumption.
418 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
CASE STUDY
George Bush’s Withholding Experiment
In early 1992, President George Bush pursued a novel policy to deal with the
lingering recession in the United States. By executive order, he lowered the
amount of income taxes that were being withheld from workers’ paychecks.The
order did not reduce the amount of taxes that workers owed; it merely delayed
payment.The higher take-home pay that workers received during 1992 was to
be offset by higher tax payments, or smaller tax refunds, when income taxes were
due in April 1993.
What effect would you predict for this policy? According to the logic of Ri-
cardian equivalence, consumers should realize that their lifetime resources were
unchanged and, therefore, save the extra take-home pay to meet the upcoming
tax liability.Yet George Bush claimed his policy would provide “money people
can use to help pay for clothing, college, or to get a new car.”That is, he be-
lieved that consumers would spend the extra income, thereby stimulating ag-
gregate demand and helping the economy recover from the recession. Bush
seemed to be assuming that consumers were shortsighted or faced binding
borrowing constraints.
Gauging the actual effects of this policy is difficult with aggregate data, be-
cause many other things were happening at the same time.Yet some evidence
comes from a survey two economists conducted shortly after the policy was an-
nounced.The survey asked people what they would do with the extra income.
Fifty-seven percent of the respondents said they would save it, use it to repay
debts, or adjust their withholding in order to reverse the effect of Bush’s execu-
tive order. Forty-three percent said they would spend the extra income.Thus, for
this policy change, a majority of the population was planning to act as Ricardian
theory posits. Nonetheless, Bush was partly right: many people planned to spend
the extra income, even though they understood that the following year’s tax bill
would be higher.
4
4
Matthew D. Shapiro and Joel Slemrod,“Consumer Response to the Timing of Income: Evidence
From a Change in Tax Withholding,” American Economic Review 85 (March 1995): 274–283.
Future Generations Besides myopia and borrowing constraints, a third argu-
ment for the traditional view of government debt is that consumers expect the
implied future taxes to fall not on them but on future generations. Suppose,
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 419:28049#/eps at 100%*28049* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
for example, that the government cuts taxes today, is-
sues 30-year bonds to finance the budget deficit, and
then raises taxes in 30 years to repay the loan. In this
case, the government debt represents a transfer of
wealth from the next generation of taxpayers (which
faces the tax hike) to the current generation of taxpay-
ers (which gets the tax cut).This transfer raises the life-
time resources of the current generation, so it raises
their consumption. In essence, a debt-financed tax cut
stimulates consumption because it gives the current
generation the opportunity to consume at the expense
of the next generation.
Economist Robert Barro has provided a clever re-
joinder to this argument to support the Ricardian view.
Barro argues that because future generations are the
children and grandchildren of the current generation,
we should not view them as independent economic ac-
tors. Instead, he argues, the appropriate assumption is
that current generations care about future generations.
This altruism between generations is evidenced by the
gifts that many people give their children, often in the
form of bequests at the time of their deaths.The exis-
tence of bequests suggests that many people are not
eager to take advantage of the opportunity to consume at their children’s
expense.
According to Barro’s analysis, the relevant decisionmaking unit is not the indi-
vidual, whose life is finite, but the family, which continues forever. In other
words, an individual decides how much to consume based not only on his own
income but also on the income of future members of his family.A debt-financed
tax cut may raise the income an individual receives in his lifetime, but it does not
raise his family’s overall resources. Instead of consuming the extra income from
the tax cut, the individual saves it and leaves it as a bequest to his children, who
will bear the future tax liability.
We can see now that the debate over government debt is really a debate over
consumer behavior. The Ricardian view assumes that consumers have a long
time horizon. Barro’s analysis of the family implies that the consumer’s time
horizon, like the government’s, is effectively infinite.Yet it is possible that con-
sumers do not look ahead to the tax liabilities of future generations. Perhaps they
expect their children to be richer than they are and therefore welcome the op-
portunity to consume at their children’s expense.The fact that many people leave
zero or minimal bequests to their children is consistent with this hypothesis. For
these zero-bequest families, a debt-financed tax cut alters consumption by redis-
tributing wealth among generations.
5
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 419
“What’s this I hear about you adults
mortgaging my future?”
Dr
awing by Dave Car
pent
er
. Fr
om the
W
all S
t
reet Journal
.
P
ermission, Car
toon Featur
es Syndicat
e.
5
Robert J. Barro, “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?’’ Journal of Political Economy 81 (1974):
1095–1117.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 420:28050#/eps at 100%*28050* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
Making a Choice
Having seen the traditional and Ricardian views of government debt, you should
ask yourself two sets of questions.
First, with which view do you agree? If the government cuts taxes today, runs
a budget deficit, and raises taxes in the future, how will the policy affect the
economy? Will it stimulate consumption, as the traditional view holds? Or will
consumers understand that their lifetime income is unchanged and, therefore,
offset the budget deficit with higher private saving?
Second, why do you hold the view that you do? If you agree with the tradi-
tional view of government debt, what is the reason? Do consumers fail to under-
stand that higher government borrowing today means higher taxes tomorrow?
Or do they ignore future taxes, either because they are borrowing-constrained or
because future taxes fall on future generations with which they do not feel an
economic link? If you hold the Ricardian view, do you believe that consumers
have the foresight to see that government borrowing today will result in future
taxes levied on them or their descendants? Do you believe that consumers will
save the extra income to offset that future tax liability?
We might hope that the evidence could help us decide between these two
views of government debt.Yet when economists examine historical episodes of
large budget deficits, the evidence is inconclusive. History can be interpreted in
different ways.
420 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
6
B. Douglas Bernheim,Andrei Shleifer, and Lawrence H. Summers,“The Strategic Bequest Mo-
tive,’’ Journal of Political Economy 93 (1985): 1045–1076.
CASE STUDY
Why Do Parents Leave Bequests?
The debate over Ricardian equivalence is partly a debate over how different gen-
erations are linked to one another. Robert Barro’s defense of the Ricardian view
is based on the assumption that parents leave their children bequests because they
care about them. But is altruism really the reason that parents leave bequests?
One group of economists has suggested that parents use bequests to control
their children. Parents often want their children to do certain things for them,
such as phoning home regularly and visiting on holidays. Perhaps parents use the
implicit threat of disinheritance to induce their children to be more attentive.
To test this “strategic bequest motive,’’ these economists examined data on
how often children visit their parents.They found that the more wealthy the par-
ent, the more often the children visit. Even more striking was another result: only
wealth that can be left as a bequest induces more frequent visits.Wealth that can-
not be bequeathed, such as pension wealth which reverts to the pension com-
pany in the event of an early death, does not encourage children to visit.These
findings suggest that there may be more to the relationships among generations
than mere altruism.
6
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 421:28051#/eps at 100%*28051* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
Consider, for example, the experience of the 1980s.The large budget deficits,
caused partly by the Reagan tax cut of 1981, seem to offer a natural experiment
to test the two views of government debt.At first glance, this episode appears de-
cisively to support the traditional view.The large budget deficits coincided with
low national saving, high real interest rates, and a large trade deficit. Indeed, ad-
vocates of the traditional view of government debt often claim that the experi-
ence of the 1980s confirms their position.
Yet those who hold the Ricardian view of government debt interpret these
events differently. Perhaps saving was low in the 1980s because people were opti-
mistic about future economic growth—an optimism that was also reflected in a
booming stock market. Or perhaps saving was low because people expected that
the tax cut would eventually lead not to higher taxes but, as Reagan promised, to
lower government spending. Because it is hard to rule out any of these interpre-
tations, both views of government debt survive.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 421
FYI
David Ricardo was a millionaire stockbroker and
one of the great economists of all time. His most
important contribution to the field was his 1817
book Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, in
which he developed the theory of comparative
advantage, which economists still use to explain
the gains from international trade. Ricardo was
also a member of the British Parliament, where
he put his own theories to work and opposed the
corn laws, which restricted international trade in
grain.
Ricardo was interested in the alternative ways
in which a government might pay for its expendi-
ture. In an 1820 article called Essay on the Funding
System, he considered an example of a war that
cost 20 million pounds. He noted that if the in-
terest rate were 5 percent, this expense could be
financed with a one-time tax of 20 million
pounds, a perpetual tax of 1 million pounds, or a
tax of 1.2 million pounds for 45 years. He wrote
In point of economy, there is no real difference in ei-
ther of the modes; for twenty million in one pay-
ment, one million per annum for ever, or 1,200,0000
pounds for 45 years, are precisely of the same value.
Ricardo was aware that the issue involved the
linkages among generations:
It would be difficult to convince a man possessed of
20,000 pounds, or any other sum, that a perpetual
Ricardo on Ricardian Equivalence
payment of 50 pounds per annum was equally bur-
densome with a single tax of 1000 pounds. He
would have some vague notion that the 50 pounds
per annum would be paid by posterity, and would
not be paid by him; but if he leaves his fortune to his
son, and leaves it charged with this perpetual tax,
where is the difference whether he leaves him 20,000
pounds with the tax, or 19,000 pounds without it?
Although Ricardo viewed these alternative meth-
ods of government finance as equivalent, he did
not think other people would view them as such:
The people who pay taxes . . . do not manage their
private affairs accordingly. We are apt to think that
the war is burdensome only in proportion to what we
are at the moment called to pay for it in taxes, with-
out reflecting on the probable duration of such taxes.
Thus, Ricardo doubted that people were rational
and farsighted enough to look ahead fully to
their future tax liabilities.
As a policymaker, Ricardo took seriously the
government debt. Before the British Parliament,
he once declared,
This would be the happiest country in the world, and
its progress in prosperity would go beyond the pow-
ers of imagination to conceive, if we got rid of two
great evils—the national debt and the corn laws.
It is one of the great ironies in the history of eco-
nomic thought that Ricardo rejected the theory
that now bears his name!
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 422:28052#/eps at 100%*28052* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
15-5 Other Perspectives on
Government Debt
The policy debates over government debt have many facets. So far we have
considered the traditional and Ricardian views of government debt.According
to the traditional view, a government budget deficit expands aggregate demand
and stimulates output in the short run but crowds out capital and depresses eco-
nomic growth in the long run.According to the Ricardian view, a government
budget deficit has none of these effects, because consumers understand that a
budget deficit represents merely the postponement of a tax burden.With these
two theories as background, we now consider several other perspectives on
government debt.
Balanced Budgets Versus Optimal Fiscal Policy
In the United States, many state constitutions require the state government to
run a balanced budget.A recurring topic of political debate is whether the fed-
eral Constitution should require a balanced budget for the federal government as
well. Most economists oppose a strict rule requiring the government to balance
its budget.There are three reasons why optimal fiscal policy may at times call for
a budget deficit or surplus.
Stabilization A budget deficit or surplus can help stabilize the economy. In
essence, a balanced-budget rule would revoke the automatic stabilizing powers
of the system of taxes and transfers.When the economy goes into a recession,
taxes automatically fall, and transfers automatically rise. Although these auto-
matic responses help stabilize the economy, they push the budget into deficit.A
strict balanced-budget rule would require that the government raise taxes or re-
duce spending in a recession, but these actions would further depress aggregate
demand.
Tax Smoothing A budget deficit or surplus can be used to reduce the distortion
of incentives caused by the tax system. As you probably learned in microeco-
nomics courses, high tax rates impose a cost on society by discouraging eco-
nomic activity. A tax on labor earnings, for instance, reduces the incentive that
people have to work long hours. Because this disincentive becomes particularly
large at very high tax rates, the total social cost of taxes is minimized by keeping
tax rates relatively stable rather than making them high in some years and low in
others. Economists call this policy tax smoothing. To keep tax rates smooth, a
deficit is necessary in years of unusually low income (recessions) or unusually
high expenditure (wars).
Intergenerational Redistribution A budget deficit can be used to shift a tax
burden from current to future generations. For example, some economists
argue that if the current generation fights a war to maintain freedom, future
generations benefit as well and should bear some of the burden. To pass on
some of the war’s costs, the current generation can finance the war with a
422 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 423:28053#/eps at 100%*28053* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
budget deficit.The government can later retire the debt by levying taxes on
the next generation.
These considerations lead most economists to reject a strict balanced-budget
rule.At the very least, a rule for fiscal policy needs to take account of the recur-
ring episodes, such as recessions and wars, during which a budget deficit is a rea-
sonable policy response.
Fiscal Effects on Monetary Policy
In 1985, Paul Volcker told Congress that “the actual and prospective size of
the budget deficit . . . heightens skepticism about our ability to control the
money supply and contain inflation.” A decade later,Alan Greenspan claimed
that “a substantial reduction in the long-term prospective deficit of the
United States will significantly lower very long-term inflation expectations.”
Both of these Fed chairmen apparently saw a link between fiscal policy and
monetary policy.
We first discussed such a possibility in Chapter 4. As we saw, one way for a
government to finance a budget deficit is simply to print money—a policy that
leads to higher inflation. Indeed, when countries experience hyperinflation, the
typical reason is that fiscal policymakers are relying on the inflation tax to pay for
some of their spending.The ends of hyperinflations almost always coincide with
fiscal reforms that include large cuts in government spending and therefore a re-
duced need for seigniorage.
In addition to this link between the budget deficit and inflation, some econo-
mists have suggested that a high level of debt might also encourage the govern-
ment to create inflation. Because most government debt is specified in nominal
terms, the real value of the debt falls when the price level rises.This is the usual
redistribution between creditors and debtors caused by unexpected inflation—
here the debtor is the government and the creditor is the private sector. But this
debtor, unlike others, has access to the monetary printing press. A high level of
debt might encourage the government to print money, thereby raising the price
level and reducing the real value of its debts.
Despite these concerns about a possible link between government debt and
monetary policy, there is little evidence that this link is important in most de-
veloped countries. In the United States, for instance, inflation was high in the
1970s, even though government debt was low relative to GDP. Monetary poli-
cymakers got inflation under control in the early 1980s, just as fiscal policy-
makers started running large budget deficits and increasing the government
debt.Thus, although monetary policy might be driven by fiscal policy in some
situations, such as during the classic hyperinflations, this situation appears not
to be the norm in most countries today.There are several reasons for this. First,
most governments can finance deficits by selling debt and don’t need to rely on
seigniorage. Second, central banks often have enough independence to resist
political pressure for more expansionary monetary policy.Third, and most im-
portant, policymakers in all parts of government know that inflation is a poor
solution to fiscal problems.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 423
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 424:28054#/eps at 100%*28054* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
Debt and the Political Process
Fiscal policy is made not by angels but by an imperfect political process. Some
economists worry that the possibility of financing government spending by issu-
ing debt makes that political process all the worse.
This idea has a long history. Nineteenth-century economist Knut Wicksell
claimed that if the benefit of some type of government spending exceeded its
cost, it should be possible to finance that spending in a way that would receive
unanimous support from the voters. He concluded that government spending
should be undertaken only when support was, in fact, nearly unanimous. In the
case of debt finance, however,Wicksell was concerned that “the interests [of fu-
ture taxpayers] are not represented at all or are represented inadequately in the
tax-approving assembly.”
Many economists have echoed this theme more recently. In their 1977 book
Democracy in Deficit, James Buchanan and Richard Wagner argued for a balanced-
budget rule for fiscal policy on the grounds that it “will have the effect of bring-
ing the real costs of public outlays to the awareness of decision makers; it will
tend to dispel the illusory ‘something for nothing’ aspects of fiscal choice.” Simi-
larly, Martin Feldstein (once an economic adviser to Ronald Reagan and a long-
time critic of budget deficits) argues that “only the ‘hard budget constraint’ of
having to balance the budget” can force politicians to judge whether spending’s
“benefits really justify its costs.”
These arguments have led some economists to favor a constitutional amend-
ment that would require Congress to pass a balanced budget. Often these pro-
posals have escape clauses for times of national emergency, such as wars and
depressions, when a budget deficit is a reasonable policy response. Some critics of
these proposals argue that, even with the escape clauses, such a constitutional
amendment would tie the hands of policymakers too severely. Others claim that
Congress would easily evade the balanced-budget requirement with accounting
tricks. As this discussion makes clear, the debate over the desirability of a
balanced-budget amendment is as much political as economic.
International Dimensions
Government debt may affect a nation’s role in the world economy. As we first
saw in Chapter 5, when a government budget deficit reduces national saving, it
often leads to a trade deficit, which in turn is financed by borrowing from
abroad. For instance, many observers have blamed U.S. fiscal policy for the recent
switch of the United States from a major creditor in the world economy to a
major debtor.This link between the budget deficit and the trade deficit leads to
two further effects of government debt.
First, high levels of government debt may increase the risk that an economy
will experience capital flight—an abrupt decline in the the demand for a
country’s assets in world financial markets. International investors are aware
that a government can always deal with its debt simply by defaulting.This ap-
proach was used as far back as 1335, when England’s King Edward III defaulted
424 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 425:28055#/eps at 100%*28055* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
on his debt to Italian bankers. More recently, several Latin American countries
defaulted on their debts in the 1980s, and Russia did the same in 1998. The
higher the level of the government debt, the greater the temptation of default.
Thus, as government debt increases, international investors may come to fear
default and curtail their lending. If this loss of confidence occurs suddenly, the
result could be the classic symptoms of capital flight: a collapse in the value of
the currency and an increase in interest rates. As we discussed in Chapter 12,
this is precisely what happened to Mexico in the early 1990s when default ap-
peared likely.
Second, high levels of government debt financed by foreign borrowing may
reduce a nation’s political clout in world affairs. This fear was emphasized by
economist Ben Friedman in his 1988 book Day of Reckoning. He wrote,“World
power and influence have historically accrued to creditor countries. It is not co-
incidental that America emerged as a world power simultaneously with our tran-
sition from a debtor nation . . . to a creditor supplying investment capital to the
rest of the world.” Friedman suggests that if the United States continues to run
large trade deficits, it will eventually lose some of its international influence. So
far, the record has not been kind to this hypothesis: the United States has run an-
other decade of trade deficits and remains a leading superpower. But perhaps
other events—such as the collapse of the Soviet Union—offset the fall in politi-
cal clout that the United States would have experienced from its increased in-
debtedness.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 425
CASE STUDY
The Benefits of Indexed Bonds
In 1997, the U.S.Treasury Department started to issue bonds that pay a return
based on the consumer price index. These bonds pay a low interest rate of
about 3.5 percent, so a $1,000 bond pays only $35 per year in interest. But that
interest payment grows with the overall price level as measured by the CPI. In
addition, when the $1,000 of principal is repaid, that amount is also adjusted
for changes in the CPI. The 3.5 percent, therefore, is a real interest rate. No
longer do professors of macroeconomics need to define the real interest rate as
an abstract construct.They can open the New York Times, point to the credit re-
port, and say,“Look here, this is a nominal interest rate, and this is a real inter-
est rate.” (Professors in the United Kingdom and several other countries have
long enjoyed this luxury because indexed bonds have been trading in other
countries for years.)
Of course, making macroeconomics easier to teach was not the reason that
the Treasury chose to index some of the government debt.That was just a posi-
tive externality. Its goal was to introduce a new type of government bond that
should benefit bondholder and taxpayer alike.These bonds are a win–win propo-
sition because they insulate both sides of the transaction from inflation risk.
Bondholders should care about the real interest rate they earn, and taxpayers
should care about the real interest rate they pay. When government bonds are
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 426:28056#/eps at 100%*28056* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
426 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
specified in nominal terms, both sides take on risk that is neither productive nor
necessary.The new indexed bonds eliminate this inflation risk.
In addition, the new bonds have three other benefits:
First, the bonds may encourage the private sector to begin issuing its own in-
dexed securities. Financial innovation is, to some extent, a public good. Once an
innovation has been introduced into the market, the idea is nonexcludable (peo-
ple cannot be prevented from using it) and nonrival (one person’s use of the idea
does not diminish other people’s use of it). Just as a free market will not ade-
quately supply the public goods of national defense and basic research, it will not
adequately supply financial innovation.The Treasury’s new bonds can be viewed
as a remedy for that market failure.
Second, the bonds reduce the government’s incentive to produce surprise in-
flation. After the large budget deficits of the 1980s and 1990s, the U.S. govern-
ment is now a substantial debtor, and its debts are specified almost entirely in
dollar terms.What is unique about the federal government, in contrast to most
debtors, is that it can print the money it needs. The greater the government’s
nominal debts, the more incentive the government has to inflate away its debt.
The Treasury’s switch toward indexed debt reduces this potentially problematic
incentive.
Third, the bonds provide data that might be useful for monetary policy.
Many macroeconomic theories point to expected inflation as a key variable to
explain the relationship between inflation and unemployment. But what is ex-
pected inflation? One way to measure it is to survey private forecasters.Another
way is to look at the difference between the yield on nominal bonds and the
yield on real bonds.
In the past, economists have proposed a variety of rules that could be used to
conduct monetary policy, as we discussed in the preceding chapter.The new in-
dexed bonds expand the number of possible rules. Here is one idea: the Fed an-
nounces a target for the inflation rate. Then, every day, the Fed measures
expected inflation as the spread between the yield on nominal debt and the yield
on indexed debt. If expected inflation is above the target, the Fed contracts the
money supply. If expected inflation is below the target, the Fed expands the
money supply. In this way, the Fed can use the bond market’s inflation forecast to
ensure that the money supply is growing at the rate needed to keep inflation
close to its target.
The Treasury’s new indexed bonds, therefore, will likely produce many bene-
fits: less inflation risk, more financial innovation, better government incentives,
more informed monetary policy, and easier lives for students and teachers of
macroeconomics.
7
7
To read more about indexed bonds, see John Y. Campbell and Robert J. Shiller,“A Scorecard for
Indexed Government Debt,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual (1996): 155–197; and David W.Wilcox,
“Policy Watch:The Introduction of Indexed Government Debt in the United States,” The Journal of
Economic Perspectives 12 (Winter 1998): 219–227.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 427:28057#/eps at 100%*28057* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
15-6 Conclusion
Fiscal policy and government debt are central in the U.S. political debate.When
Bill Clinton became president in 1993, he made reducing the budget deficit a
high priority of his administration.When the Republicans took control of Con-
gress in 1995, they pushed for even faster deficit reduction than Clinton had ad-
vocated. These efforts together with some good luck turned the federal
government budget from deficit to surplus by the late 1990s.When George W.
Bush moved into the White House in 2001, the policy debate was over how
quickly the government should pay off its debts.
This chapter discussed some of the economic issues that lie behind these pol-
icy decisions.As we have seen, economists are not in complete agreement about
the measurement or effects of government indebtedness. Given the profound
importance of this topic, there seems little doubt that the debates will continue
in the years to come.
Summary
1. The current debt of the U.S. federal government is of moderate size com-
pared to the debt of other countries or compared to the debt that the United
States has had throughout its own history.The 1980s and early 1990s were
unusual in that the ratio of debt to GDP increased during a period of peace
and prosperity. Since 1995, the debt–GDP ratio has declined substantially.
2. Standard measures of the budget deficit are imperfect measures of fiscal pol-
icy because they do not correct for the effects of inflation, do not offset
changes in government liabilities with changes in government assets, omit
some liabilities altogether, and do not correct for the effects of the business
cycle.
3. According to the traditional view of government debt, a debt-financed tax
cut stimulates consumer spending and lowers national saving.This increase in
consumer spending leads to greater aggregate demand and higher income in
the short run, but it leads to a lower capital stock and lower income in the
long run.
4. According to the Ricardian view of government debt, a debt-financed tax
cut does not stimulate consumer spending because it does not raise con-
sumers’ overall resources—it merely reschedules taxes from the present to
the future.The debate between the traditional and Ricardian views of gov-
ernment debt is ultimately a debate over how consumers behave. Are con-
sumers rational or shortsighted? Do they face binding borrowing
constraints? Are they economically linked to future generations through al-
truistic bequests? Economists’ views of government debt hinge on their an-
swers to these questions.
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 427
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 428:28058#/eps at 100%*28058* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
428 | PART V Microeconomic Policy Debates
KEY CONCEPTS
Capital budgeting Cyclically adjusted budget deficit Ricardian equivalence
1. What was unusual about U.S. fiscal policy from
1980 to 1995?
2. Why do many economists project increasing
budget deficits and government debt over the
next several decades?
3. Describe four problems affecting measurement of
the government budget deficit.
4. According to the traditional view of government
debt, how does a debt-financed tax cut affect
public saving, private saving, and national saving?
QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW
5. According to the Ricardian view of government
debt, how does a debt-financed tax cut affect
public saving, private saving, and national saving?
6. Do you believe the traditional or the Ricardian
view of government debt? Why?
7. Give three reasons why a budget deficit might be
a good policy choice.
8. Why might the level of government debt affect
the government’s incentives regarding money
creation?
PROBLEMS AND APPLICATIONS
1. On April 1, 1996,Taco Bell, the fast-food chain,
ran a full-page ad in the New York Times with this
news:“In an effort to help the national debt,Taco
Bell is pleased to announce that we have agreed
to purchase the Liberty Bell, one of our country’s
most historic treasures. It will now be called the
Taco Liberty Bell and will still be accessible to the
American public for viewing.We hope our move
will prompt other corporations to take similar ac-
tion to do their part to reduce the country’s
debt.” Would such actions by U.S. corporations
actually reduce the national debt as it is now mea-
sured? How would your answer change if the
U.S. government adopted capital budgeting? Do
you think these actions represent a true reduction
in the government’s indebtedness? Do you think
Taco Bell was serious about this plan? (Hint:
Note the date.)
2. Draft a letter to the senator described in Section
15-3, explaining and evaluating the Ricardian
view of government debt.
3. The Social Security system levies a tax on work-
ers and pays benefits to the elderly. Suppose that
5. Most economists oppose a strict rule requiring a balanced budget. A budget
deficit can sometimes be justified on the basis of short-run stabilization, tax
smoothing, or intergenerational redistribution of the tax burden.
6. Government debt can potentially have other effects. Large government debt
or budget deficits may encourage excessive monetary expansion and, there-
fore, lead to greater inflation.The possibility of running budget deficits may
encourage politicians to unduly burden future generations when setting gov-
ernment spending and taxes.A high level of government debt may risk capi-
tal flight and diminish a nation’s influence around the world. Economists
differ in which of these effects they consider most important.
User LUKBI:Job EFF01431:6264_ch15:Pg 429:28059#/eps at 100%*28059* Wed, Feb 20, 2002 3:29 PM
Congress increases both the tax and the benefits.
For simplicity,assume that the Congress announces
that the increases will last for one year only.
a. How do you suppose this change would affect
the economy? (Hint:Think about the marginal
propensities to consume of the young and the
old.)
b. Does your answer depend on whether genera-
tions are altruistically linked?
4. Evaluate the usefulness of generational account-
ing from the perspective of someone who be-
lieves that generations are altruistically linked.
Now evaluate the usefulness of generational ac-
counting from the perspective of someone who
believes that many consumers face binding bor-
rowing constraints.
5. The cyclically adjusted budget deficit is the budget
deficit corrected for the effects of the business
cycle. In other words, it is the budget deficit that
the government would be running if unemploy-
ment were at the natural rate. (It is also called the
full-employment budget deficit.) Some economists
have proposed the rule that the cyclically adjusted
budget deficit always be balanced. Compare this
proposal to a strict balanced-budget rule. Which
is preferable? What problems do you see with the
rule requiring a balanced cyclically adjusted bud-
get?
6. Using the library or the Internet, find some re-
cent projections for the future path of the U.S.
government debt as a percentage of GDP. What
assumptions are made about government spend-
ing, taxes, and economic growth? Do you think
these assumptions are reasonable? If the U.S. ex-
periences a productivity slowdown, how will re-
ality differ from this projection? (Hint: A good
place to look is www.cbo.gov.)
CHAPTER 15 Government Debt | 429