User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 347:25876#/eps at 100%*25876* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
Most economists analyze short-run fluctuations in aggregate income and the
price level using the model of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. In the
previous three chapters, we examined aggregate demand in some detail. The
IS–LM model—together with its open-economy cousin the Mundell–Fleming
model—shows how changes in monetary and fiscal policy and shocks to the
money and goods markets shift the aggregate demand curve. In this chapter, we
turn our attention to aggregate supply and develop theories that explain the po-
sition and slope of the aggregate supply curve.
When we introduced the aggregate supply curve in Chapter 9, we established
that aggregate supply behaves differently in the short run than in the long run. In
the long run, prices are flexible, and the aggregate supply curve is vertical.When
the aggregate supply curve is vertical, shifts in the aggregate demand curve affect
the price level, but the output of the economy remains at its natural rate. By con-
trast, in the short run, prices are sticky, and the aggregate supply curve is not ver-
tical. In this case, shifts in aggregate demand do cause fluctuations in output. In
Chapter 9 we took a simplified view of price stickiness by drawing the short-run
aggregate supply curve as a horizontal line, representing the extreme situation in
which all prices are fixed. Our task now is to refine this understanding of short-
run aggregate supply.
Unfortunately, one fact makes this task more difficult: economists disagree
about how best to explain aggregate supply. As a result, this chapter begins by
presenting three prominent models of the short-run aggregate supply curve.
Among economists, each of these models has some prominent adherents (as well
as some prominent critics), and you can decide for yourself which you find most
plausible. Although these models differ in some significant details, they are also
related in an important way: they share a common theme about what makes the
| 347
13
Aggregate Supply
CHAPTER
There is always a temporary tradeoff between inflation and unemploy-
ment; there is no permanent tradeoff. The temporary tradeoff comes not
from inflation per se, but from unanticipated inflation, which generally
means, from a rising rate of inflation.
— Milton Friedman
THIRTEEN
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 348:27755#/eps at 100%*27755* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
short-run and long-run aggregate supply curves differ and a common conclusion
that the short-run aggregate supply curve is upward sloping.
After examining the models, we examine an implication of the short-run ag-
gregate supply curve. We show that this curve implies a tradeoff between two
measures of economic performance—inflation and unemployment.According to
this tradeoff, to reduce the rate of inflation policymakers must temporarily raise
unemployment, and to reduce unemployment they must accept higher inflation.
As the quotation at the beginning of the chapter suggests, the tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment is only temporary. One goal of this chapter is to ex-
plain why policymakers face such a tradeoff in the short run and, just as impor-
tant, why they do not face it in the long run.
13-1 Three Models of Aggregate Supply
When classes in physics study balls rolling down inclined planes, they often begin
by assuming away the existence of friction.This assumption makes the problem
simpler and is useful in many circumstances, but no good engineer would ever
take this assumption as a literal description of how the world works. Similarly,
this book began with classical macroeconomic theory, but it would be a mistake
to assume that this model is always true. Our job now is to look more deeply
into the “frictions” of macroeconomics.
We do this by examining three prominent models of aggregate supply,
roughly in the order of their development. In all the models, some market im-
perfection (that is, some type of friction) causes the output of the economy to
deviate from the classical benchmark.As a result, the short-run aggregate sup-
ply curve is upward sloping, rather than vertical, and shifts in the aggregate
demand curve cause the level of output to deviate temporarily from the nat-
ural rate. These temporary deviations represent the booms and busts of the
business cycle.
Although each of the three models takes us down a different theoretical route,
each route ends up in the same place.That final destination is a short-run aggre-
gate supply equation of the form
Y =Y
?
+
a
(P ?P
e
),
a
> 0
where Y is output, Y
?
is the natural rate of output, P is the price level, and P
e
is
the expected price level.This equation states that output deviates from its natural
rate when the price level deviates from the expected price level.The parameter
a
indicates how much output responds to unexpected changes in the price level;
1/
a
is the slope of the aggregate supply curve.
Each of the three models tells a different story about what lies behind this
short-run aggregate supply equation. In other words, each highlights a particular
reason why unexpected movements in the price level are associated with fluctu-
ations in aggregate output.
348 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 349:27756#/eps at 100%*27756* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
The Sticky-Wage Model
To explain why the short-run aggregate supply curve is upward sloping, many
economists stress the sluggish adjustment of nominal wages. In many industries,
nominal wages are set by long-term contracts, so wages cannot adjust quickly
when economic conditions change. Even in industries not covered by formal
contracts, implicit agreements between workers and firms may limit wage
changes. Wages may also depend on social norms and notions of fairness that
evolve slowly. For these reasons, many economists believe that nominal wages are
sticky in the short run.
The sticky-wage model shows what a sticky nominal wage implies for ag-
gregate supply.To preview the model, consider what happens to the amount of
output produced when the price level rises:
1. When the nominal wage is stuck, a rise in the price level lowers the real wage,
making labor cheaper.
2. The lower real wage induces firms to hire more labor.
3. The additional labor hired produces more output.
This positive relationship between the price level and the amount of output
means that the aggregate supply curve slopes upward during the time when the
nominal wage cannot adjust.
To develop this story of aggregate supply more formally, assume that workers
and firms bargain over and agree on the nominal wage before they know what
the price level will be when their agreement takes effect. The bargaining par-
ties—the workers and the firms—have in mind a target real wage.The target may
be the real wage that equilibrates labor supply and demand. More likely, the tar-
get real wage is higher than the equilibrium real wage: as discussed in Chapter 6,
union power and efficiency-wage considerations tend to keep real wages above
the level that brings supply and demand into balance.
The workers and firms set the nominal wage W based on the target real wage
q
and on their expectation of the price level P
e
.The nominal wage they set is
W =
q
× P
e
Nominal Wage = Target Real Wage × Expected Price Level.
After the nominal wage has been set and before labor has been hired, firms learn
the actual price level P.The real wage turns out to be
W/P =
q
× (P
e
/P)
Real Wage = Target Real Wage × .
This equation shows that the real wage deviates from its target if the actual price
level differs from the expected price level.When the actual price level is greater
than expected, the real wage is less than its target; when the actual price level is
less than expected, the real wage is greater than its target.
Expected Price Level
???
Actual Price Level
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 349
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 350:27757#/eps at 100%*27757* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
The final assumption of the sticky-wage model is that employment is deter-
mined by the quantity of labor that firms demand. In other words, the bargain
between the workers and the firms does not determine the level of employment
in advance; instead, the workers agree to provide as much labor as the firms wish
to buy at the predetermined wage.We describe the firms’ hiring decisions by the
labor demand function
L = L
d
(W/P),
which states that the lower the real wage, the more labor firms hire.The labor
demand curve is shown in panel (a) of Figure 13-1. Output is determined by the
production function
Y = F(L),
which states that the more labor is hired, the more output is produced.This is
shown in panel (b) of Figure 13-1.
Panel (c) of Figure 13-1 shows the resulting aggregate supply curve. Be-
cause the nominal wage is sticky, an unexpected change in the price level
350 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 13-1
Real wage,
W/P
Income, output, Y
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
Labor, L Labor, L
W/P
1
W/P
2
L H11005 L
d
(W/P)
L
2
L
1
Y
2
Y
1
Y H11005 F(L)
L
2
L
1
P
2
P
1
Y H11005 Y H11001 a(P H11002 P
e
)
Y
2
Y
1
1. An increase
in the price
level . . .
3. . . .which raises
employment, . . .
4. . . . output, . . .
5. . . . and income.
2. . . . reduces
the real wage
for a given
nominal wage, . . .
6. The aggregate
supply curve
summarizes
these changes.
(a) Labor Demand (b) Production Function
(c) Aggregate Supply
The Sticky-Wage Model Panel (a)
shows the labor demand curve. Because
the nominal wage W is stuck, an increase
in the price level from P
1
to P
2
reduces
the real wage from W/P
1
to W/P
2
. The
lower real wage raises the quantity of
labor demanded from L
1
to L
2
. Panel (b)
shows the production function. An
increase in the quantity of labor from
L
1
to L
2
raises output from Y
1
to Y
2
.
Panel (c) shows the aggregate supply
curve summarizing this relationship
between the price level and output. An
increase in the price level from P
1
to P
2
raises output from Y
1
to Y
2
.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 351:27758#/eps at 100%*27758* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
moves the real wage away from the target real wage, and this change in the real
wage influences the amounts of labor hired and output produced.The aggre-
gate supply curve can be written as
Y =Y
?
+
a
(P ?P
e
).
Output deviates from its natural level when the price level deviates from the ex-
pected price level.
1
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 351
1
For more on the sticky-wage model, see Jo Anna Gray,“Wage Indexation:A Macroeconomic Ap-
proach,’’ Journal of Monetary Economics 2 (April 1976): 221–235; and Stanley Fischer, “Long-Term
Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule,’’ Journal of Political Econ-
omy 85 (February 1977): 191–205.
2
For some of the recent work on the cyclical behavior of the real wage, see Scott Sumner and
Stephen Silver,“Real Wages, Employment, and the Phillips Curve,’’ Journal of Political Economy 97
( June 1989): 706–720; and Gary Solon, Robert Barsky, and Jonathan A. Parker, “Measuring the
Cyclicality of Real Wages: How Important Is Composition Bias?’’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 109
(February 1994): 1–25.
CASE STUDY
The Cyclical Behavior of the Real Wage
In any model with an unchanging labor demand curve, such as the model we
just discussed, employment rises when the real wage falls. In the sticky-wage
model, an unexpected rise in the price level lowers the real wage and thereby
raises the quantity of labor hired and the amount of output produced.Thus, the
real wage should be countercyclical: it should fluctuate in the opposite direction
from employment and output. Keynes himself wrote in The General Theory that
“an increase in employment can only occur to the accompaniment of a decline
in the rate of real wages.’’
The earliest attacks on The General Theory came from economists challenging
Keynes’s prediction. Figure 13-2 is a scatterplot of the percentage change in real
compensation per hour and the percentage change in real GDP using annual
data for the U.S. economy from 1960 to 2000. If Keynes’s prediction were cor-
rect, the dots in this figure would show a downward-sloping pattern, indicating a
negative relationship.Yet the figure shows only a weak correlation between the
real wage and output, and it is the opposite of what Keynes predicted.That is, if
the real wage is cyclical at all, it is slightly procyclical: the real wage tends to rise
when output rises.Abnormally high labor costs cannot explain the low employ-
ment and output observed in recessions.
How should we interpret this evidence? Most economists conclude that the
sticky-wage model cannot fully explain aggregate supply.They advocate models
in which the labor demand curve shifts over the business cycle.These shifts may
arise because firms have sticky prices and cannot sell all they want at those
prices; we discuss this possibility later.Alternatively, the labor demand curve may
shift because of shocks to technology, which alter labor productivity.The theory
we discuss in Chapter 19, called the theory of real business cycles, gives a promi-
nent role to technology shocks as a source of economic fluctuations.
2
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 352:27759#/eps at 100%*27759* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
The Imperfect-Information Model
The second explanation for the upward slope of the short-run aggregate supply
curve is called the imperfect-information model. Unlike the sticky-wage
model, this model assumes that markets clear—that is, all wages and prices are free
to adjust to balance supply and demand. In this model, the short-run and long-run
aggregate supply curves differ because of temporary misperceptions about prices.
The imperfect-information model assumes that each supplier in the economy
produces a single good and consumes many goods. Because the number of goods
is so large, suppliers cannot observe all prices at all times.They monitor closely
the prices of what they produce but less closely the prices of all the goods they
consume. Because of imperfect information, they sometimes confuse changes in
the overall level of prices with changes in relative prices.This confusion influ-
ences decisions about how much to supply, and it leads to a positive relationship
between the price level and output in the short run.
Consider the decision facing a single supplier—a wheat farmer, for instance.
Because the farmer earns income from selling wheat and uses this income to buy
goods and services, the amount of wheat she chooses to produce depends on the
352 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 13-2
Percentage
change in real
wage
Percentage change in real GDP
1982
1975
1993
1992
1960
1996
1999
1997
1998
1979
1970
1980
1991
1974
1990
1984
2000
1972
1965
H110023 H110022 H1100210 1 2 3 7 8654
4
3
2
1
0
H110021
H110022
H110023
H110024
H110025
The Cyclical Behavior of the Real Wage This scatterplot shows the percentage change in
real GDP and the percentage change in the real wage (measured here as real private
hourly earnings). As output fluctuates, the real wage typically moves in the same
direction. That is, the real wage is somewhat procyclical. This observation is inconsistent
with the sticky-wage model.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. Department of Labor.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 353:27760#/eps at 100%*27760* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
price of wheat relative to the prices of other goods and services in the economy.
If the relative price of wheat is high, the farmer is motivated to work hard and
produce more wheat, because the reward is great. If the relative price of wheat is
low, she prefers to enjoy more leisure and produce less wheat.
Unfortunately, when the farmer makes her production decision, she does not
know the relative price of wheat. As a wheat producer, she monitors the wheat
market closely and always knows the nominal price of wheat. But she does not
know the prices of all the other goods in the economy. She must, therefore, esti-
mate the relative price of wheat using the nominal price of wheat and her ex-
pectation of the overall price level.
Consider how the farmer responds if all prices in the economy, including the
price of wheat, increase. One possibility is that she expected this change in
prices.When she observes an increase in the price of wheat, her estimate of its
relative price is unchanged. She does not work any harder.
The other possibility is that the farmer did not expect the price level to increase
(or to increase by this much).When she observes the increase in the price of wheat,
she is not sure whether other prices have risen (in which case wheat’s relative price
is unchanged) or whether only the price of wheat has risen (in which case its rela-
tive price is higher).The rational inference is that some of each has happened. In
other words, the farmer infers from the increase in the nominal price of wheat that
its relative price has risen somewhat. She works harder and produces more.
Our wheat farmer is not unique.When the price level rises unexpectedly, all
suppliers in the economy observe increases in the prices of the goods they pro-
duce.They all infer, rationally but mistakenly, that the relative prices of the goods
they produce have risen.They work harder and produce more.
To sum up, the imperfect-information model says that when actual prices ex-
ceed expected prices, suppliers raise their output.The model implies an aggre-
gate supply curve that is now familiar:
Y =Y
?
+
a
(P ?P
e
).
Output deviates from the natural rate when the price level deviates from the ex-
pected price level.
3
The Sticky-Price Model
Our third explanation for the upward-sloping short-run aggregate supply curve
is called the sticky-price model.This model emphasizes that firms do not in-
stantly adjust the prices they charge in response to changes in demand. Some-
times prices are set by long-term contracts between firms and customers. Even
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 353
3
Two economists who have emphasized the role of imperfect information for understanding the
short-run effects of monetary policy are the Nobel Prize winners Milton Friedman and Robert
Lucas. See Milton Friedman,“The Role of Monetary Policy,’’ American Economic Review 58 (March
1968): 1–17; and Robert E. Lucas, Jr.,“Understanding Business Cycles,’’ Stabilization of the Domestic
and International Economy, vol. 5 of Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy (Amsterdam:
North-Holland, 1977).
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 354:27761#/eps at 100%*27761* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
without formal agreements, firms may hold prices steady in order not to annoy
their regular customers with frequent price changes. Some prices are sticky be-
cause of the way markets are structured: once a firm has printed and distributed
its catalog or price list, it is costly to alter prices.
To see how sticky prices can help explain an upward-sloping aggregate supply
curve, we first consider the pricing decisions of individual firms and then add to-
gether the decisions of many firms to explain the behavior of the economy as a
whole. Notice that this model encourages us to depart from the assumption of
perfect competition, which we have used since Chapter 3. Perfectly competitive
firms are price takers rather than price setters. If we want to consider how firms
set prices, it is natural to assume that these firms have at least some monopoly
control over the prices they charge.
Consider the pricing decision facing a typical firm.The firm’s desired price p
depends on two macroeconomic variables:
? The overall level of prices P. A higher price level implies that the firm’s
costs are higher. Hence, the higher the overall price level, the more the
firm would like to charge for its product.
? The level of aggregate income Y. A higher level of income raises the de-
mand for the firm’s product. Because marginal cost increases at higher levels
of production, the greater the demand, the higher the firm’s desired price.
We write the firm’s desired price as
p = P + a(Y ?Y
?
).
This equation says that the desired price p depends on the overall level of prices
P and on the level of aggregate output relative to the natural rate Y ?Y
?
.The pa-
rameter a (which is greater than zero) measures how much the firm’s desired
price responds to the level of aggregate output.
4
Now assume that there are two types of firms. Some have flexible prices: they
always set their prices according to this equation. Others have sticky prices: they
announce their prices in advance based on what they expect economic condi-
tions to be. Firms with sticky prices set prices according to
p = P
e
+ a(Y
e
?Y
?
e
),
where, as before, a superscript “e’’ represents the expected value of a variable. For
simplicity, assume that these firms expect output to be at its natural rate, so that
the last term, a(Y
e
?Y
?
e
), is zero.Then these firms set the price
p = P
e
.
That is, firms with sticky prices set their prices based on what they expect other
firms to charge.
354 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
4
Mathematical note: The firm cares most about its relative price, which is the ratio of its nominal
price to the overall price level. If we interpret p and P as the logarithms of the firm’s price and the
price level, then this equation states that the desired relative price depends on the deviation of out-
put from the natural rate.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 355:27762#/eps at 100%*27762* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
We can use the pricing rules of the two groups of firms to derive the aggre-
gate supply equation.To do this, we find the overall price level in the economy,
which is the weighted average of the prices set by the two groups. If s is the frac-
tion of firms with sticky prices and 1 ? s the fraction with flexible prices, then
the overall price level is
P = sP
e
+ (1 ? s)[P + a(Y ?Y
?
)].
The first term is the price of the sticky-price firms weighted by their fraction in
the economy, and the second term is the price of the flexible-price firms weighted
by their fraction. Now subtract (1 ? s)P from both sides of this equation to obtain
sP = sP
e
+ (1 ? s)[a(Y ?Y
?
)].
Divide both sides by s to solve for the overall price level:
P = P
e
+ [(1 ? s)a/s](Y ?Y
?
)].
The two terms in this equation are explained as follows:
? When firms expect a high price level, they expect high costs.Those firms
that fix prices in advance set their prices high.These high prices cause the
other firms to set high prices also. Hence, a high expected price level P
e
leads to a high actual price level P.
? When output is high, the demand for goods is high.Those firms with
flexible prices set their prices high, which leads to a high price level.The
effect of output on the price level depends on the proportion of firms
with flexible prices.
Hence, the overall price level depends on the expected price level and on the
level of output.
Algebraic rearrangement puts this aggregate pricing equation into a more fa-
miliar form:
Y =Y
?
+
a
(P ?P
e
),
where
a
= s/[(1 ? s)a]. Like the other models, the sticky-price model says that
the deviation of output from the natural rate is positively associated with the de-
viation of the price level from the expected price level.
Although the sticky-price model emphasizes the goods market, consider
briefly what is happening in the labor market. If a firm’s price is stuck in the
short run, then a reduction in aggregate demand reduces the amount that the
firm is able to sell.The firm responds to the drop in sales by reducing its produc-
tion and its demand for labor. Note the contrast to the sticky-wage model: the
firm here does not move along a fixed labor demand curve. Instead, fluctuations
in output are associated with shifts in the labor demand curve. Because of these
shifts in labor demand, employment, production, and the real wage can all move
in the same direction.Thus, the real wage can be procyclical.
5
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 355
5
For a more advanced development of the sticky-price model, see Julio Rotemberg,“Monopolis-
tic Price Adjustment and Aggregate Output,’’ Review of Economic Studies 49 (1982): 517–531.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 356:27763#/eps at 100%*27763* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
356 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
CASE STUDY
International Differences in the Aggregate Supply Curve
Although all countries experience economic fluctuations, these fluctuations are
not exactly the same everywhere. International differences are intriguing puzzles
in themselves, and they often provide a way to test alternative economic theories.
Examining international differences has been especially fruitful in research on
aggregate supply.
When economist Robert Lucas proposed the imperfect-information model, he
derived a surprising interaction between aggregate demand and aggregate supply:
according to his model, the slope of the aggregate supply curve should depend on
the volatility of aggregate demand. In countries where aggregate demand fluctuates
widely, the aggregate price level fluctuates widely as well. Because most movements
in prices in these countries do not represent movements in relative prices, suppliers
should have learned not to respond much to unexpected changes in the price level.
Therefore, the aggregate supply curve should be relatively steep (that is,
a
will be
small).Conversely,in countries where aggregate demand is relatively stable,suppliers
should have learned that most price changes are relative price changes.Accordingly,
in these countries, suppliers should be more responsive to unexpected price
changes, making the aggregate supply curve relatively flat (that is,
a
will be large).
Lucas tested this prediction by examining international data on output and
prices. He found that changes in aggregate demand have the biggest effect on
output in those countries where aggregate demand and prices are most stable.
Lucas concluded that the evidence supports the imperfect-information model.
6
The sticky-price model also makes predictions about the slope of the short-
run aggregate supply curve. In particular, it predicts that the average rate of infla-
tion should influence the slope of the short-run aggregate supply curve.When
the average rate of inflation is high, it is very costly for firms to keep prices fixed
for long intervals.Thus, firms adjust prices more frequently. More frequent price
adjustment in turn allows the overall price level to respond more quickly to
shocks to aggregate demand. Hence, a high rate of inflation should make the
short-run aggregate supply curve steeper.
International data support this prediction of the sticky-price model. In coun-
tries with low average inflation, the short-run aggregate supply curve is relatively
flat: fluctuations in aggregate demand have large effects on output and are slowly
reflected in prices. High-inflation countries have steep short-run aggregate sup-
ply curves. In other words, high inflation appears to erode the frictions that cause
prices to be sticky.
7
Note that the sticky-price model can also explain Lucas’s finding that coun-
tries with variable aggregate demand have steep aggregate supply curves. If the
price level is highly variable, few firms will commit to prices in advance (s will
be small). Hence, the aggregate supply curve will be steep (
a
will be small).
6
Robert E. Lucas, Jr.,“Some International Evidence on Output-Inflation Tradeoffs,’’ American Eco-
nomic Review 63 ( June 1973): 326–334.
7
Laurence Ball, N. Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer,“The New Keynesian Economics and the
Output-Inflation Tradeoff,’’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1988:1): 1–65.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 357:27764#/eps at 100%*27764* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
Summary and Implications
We have seen three models of aggregate supply and the market imperfection that
each uses to explain why the short-run aggregate supply curve is upward slop-
ing. One model assumes nominal wages are sticky; the second assumes informa-
tion about prices is imperfect; the third assumes prices are sticky. Keep in mind
that these models are not incompatible with one another. We need not accept
one model and reject the others.The world may contain all three of these market
imperfections, and all may contribute to the behavior of short-run aggregate
supply.
Although the three models of aggregate supply differ in their assumptions and
emphases, their implications for aggregate output are similar.All can be summa-
rized by the equation
Y =Y
?
+
a
(P ?P
e
).
This equation states that deviations of output from the natural rate are related to
deviations of the price level from the expected price level. If the price level is higher
than the expected price level, output exceeds its natural rate. If the price level is lower than
the expected price level, output falls short of its natural rate. Figure 13-3 graphs this
equation. Notice that the short-run aggregate supply curve is drawn for a given
expectation P
e
and that a change in P
e
would shift the curve.
Now that we have a better understanding of aggregate supply, let’s put ag-
gregate supply and aggregate demand back together. Figure 13-4 uses our ag-
gregate supply equation to show how the economy responds to an unexpected
increase in aggregate demand attributable, say, to an unexpected monetary ex-
pansion. In the short run, the equilibrium moves from point A to point B. The
increase in aggregate demand raises the actual price level from P
1
to P
2
. Because
people did not expect this increase in the price level, the expected price level
remains at P
2
e
, and output rises from Y
1
to Y
2
, which is above the natural rate
Y
?
. Thus, the unexpected expansion in aggregate demand causes the economy
to boom.
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 357
figure 13-3
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
P = P
e
P > P
e
P < P
e
Y H11005 Y H11001 a(P H11002 P
e
)
Y
Short-run
aggregate supply
Long-run
aggregate
supply
The Short-Run Aggregate
Supply Curve Output
deviates from the natural rate
Y
?
if the price level P deviates
from the expected price level
P
e
.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 358:27765#/eps at 100%*27765* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
Yet the boom does not last forever. In the long run, the expected price level
rises to catch up with reality, causing the short-run aggregate supply curve to
shift upward.As the expected price level rises from P
2
e
to P
3
e
, the equilibrium of
the economy moves from point B to point C.The actual price level rises from P
2
to P
3
, and output falls from Y
2
to Y
3
. In other words, the economy returns to the
natural level of output in the long run, but at a much higher price level.
This analysis shows an important principle, which holds for each of the three
models of aggregate supply: long-run monetary neutrality and short-run mone-
tary nonneutrality are perfectly compatible. Short-run nonneutrality is repre-
sented here by the movement from point A to point B, and long-run monetary
neutrality is represented by the movement from point A to point C.We reconcile
the short-run and long-run effects of money by emphasizing the adjustment of
expectations about the price level.
13-2 Inflation, Unemployment, and the
Phillips Curve
Two goals of economic policymakers are low inflation and low unemployment,
but often these goals conflict. Suppose, for instance, that policymakers were to
use monetary or fiscal policy to expand aggregate demand. This policy would
move the economy along the short-run aggregate supply curve to a point of
higher output and a higher price level. (Figure 13-4 shows this as the change
from point A to point B.) Higher output means lower unemployment, because
firms need more workers when they produce more. A higher price level, given
358 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 13-4
Price level, P
Income,
output, Y
C
P
3
H11005 P
3
e
P
1
H11005 P
1
e
H11005 P
2
e
P
2
A
B
AD
2
AD
1
AS
1
AS
2
Long-run
increase in
price level
Short-run
increase in
price level
Short-run fluctuation
in output Y
1
H11005 Y
3
H11005 Y
Y
2
How Shifts in Aggregate Demand
Lead to Short-Run Fluctuations Here
the economy begins in a long-run
equilibrium, point A. When aggregate
demand increases unexpectedly, the price
level rises from P
1
to P
2
. Because the
price level P
2
is above the expected price
level P
2
e
, output rises temporarily above
the natural rate, as the economy moves
along the short-run aggregate supply
curve from point A to point B. In the long
run, the expected price level rises to P
3
e
,
causing the short-run aggregate supply
curve to shift upward. The economy
returns to a new long-run equilbrium,
point C, where output is back at its
natural rate.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 359:27766#/eps at 100%*27766* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
the previous year’s price level, means higher inflation.Thus, when policymakers
move the economy up along the short-run aggregate supply curve, they reduce
the unemployment rate and raise the inflation rate. Conversely, when they con-
tract aggregate demand and move the economy down the short-run aggregate
supply curve, unemployment rises and inflation falls.
This tradeoff between inflation and unemployment, called the Phillips curve,
is our topic in this section. As we have just seen (and will derive more for-
mally in a moment), the Phillips curve is a reflection of the short-run aggre-
gate supply curve: as policymakers move the economy along the short-run
aggregate supply curve, unemployment and inflation move in opposite direc-
tions. The Phillips curve is a useful way to express aggregate supply because
inflation and unemployment are such important measures of economic per-
formance.
Deriving the Phillips Curve From the Aggregate
Supply Curve
The Phillips curve in its modern form states that the inflation rate depends on
three forces:
? Expected inflation;
? The deviation of unemployment from the natural rate, called cyclical unem-
ployment;
? Supply shocks.
These three forces are expressed in the following equation:
p
=
p
e
?
b
(u ? u
n
) +
u
Inflation =?(
b
× ) + ,
where
b
is a parameter measuring the response of inflation to cyclical unemploy-
ment. Notice that there is a minus sign before the cyclical unemployment term:
high unemployment tends to reduce inflation.This equation summarizes the re-
lationship between inflation and unemployment.
From where does this equation for the Phillips curve come? Although it may
not seem familiar, we can derive it from our equation for aggregate supply.To see
how, write the aggregate supply equation as
P = P
e
+ (1/
a
)(Y ?Y
?
).
With one addition, one subtraction, and one substitution, we can manipulate this
equation to yield a relationship between inflation and unemployment.
Here are the three steps. First, add to the right-hand side of the equation a
supply shock
u
to represent exogenous events (such as a change in world oil
prices) that alter the price level and shift the short-run aggregate supply curve:
P = P
e
+ (1/
a
)(Y ?Y
?
) +
u
.
Supply
Shock
Cyclical
Unemployment
Expected
Inflation
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 359
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 360:27767#/eps at 100%*27767* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
Next, to go from the price level to inflation rates, subtract last year’s price level
P
?1
from both sides of the equation to obtain
(P ? P
?1
) = (P
e
? P
?1
) + (1/
a
)(Y ?Y
?
) +
u
.
The term on the left-hand side,P ? P
?1
,is the difference between the current price
level and last year’s price level, which is inflation
p
.
8
The term on the right-hand
side, P
e
? P
?1
, is the difference between the expected price level and last year’s
price level,which is expected inflation
p
e
.Therefore,we can replace P ? P
?1
with
p
and P
e
? P
?1
with
p
e
:
p
=
p
e
+ (1/
a
)(Y ?Y
?
) +
u
.
Third, to go from output to unemployment, recall from Chapter 2 that Okun’s
law gives a relationship between these two variables. One version of Okun’s law
states that the deviation of output from its natural rate is inversely related to the
deviation of unemployment from its natural rate; that is, when output is higher
than the natural rate of output, unemployment is lower than the natural rate of
unemployment.We can write this as
(1/
a
)(Y ?Y
?
) =?
b
(u ? u
n
).
Using this Okun’s law relationship, we can substitute ?
b
(u ? u
n
) for (1/
a
)(Y ? Y
?
)
in the previous equation to obtain
p
=
p
e
?
b
(u ? u
n
) +
u
.
Thus, we can derive the Phillips curve equation from the aggregate supply
equation.
All this algebra is meant to show one thing: the Phillips curve equation and
the short-run aggregate supply equation represent essentially the same macro-
economic ideas. In particular, both equations show a link between real and
nominal variables that causes the classical dichotomy (the theoretical separa-
tion of real and nominal variables) to break down in the short run.According
to the short-run aggregate supply equation, output is related to unexpected
movements in the price level. According to the Phillips curve equation, un-
employment is related to unexpected movements in the inflation rate.The ag-
gregate supply curve is more convenient when we are studying output and
the price level, whereas the Phillips curve is more convenient when we are
studying unemployment and inflation. But we should not lose sight of the fact
that the Phillips curve and the aggregate supply curve are two sides of the
same coin.
360 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
8
Mathematical note: This statement is not precise, because inflation is really the percentage change in
the price level.To make the statement more precise, interpret P as the logarithm of the price level.
By the properties of logarithms, the change in P is roughly the inflation rate.The reason is that
dP = d(log price level) = d(price level)/price level.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 361:27768#/eps at 100%*27768* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
Adaptive Expectations and Inflation Inertia
To make the Phillips curve useful for analyzing the choices facing policymakers,
we need to say what determines expected inflation.A simple and often plausible
assumption is that people form their expectations of inflation based on recently
observed inflation.This assumption is called adaptive expectations. For exam-
ple, suppose that people expect prices to rise this year at the same rate as they did
last year.Then expected inflation
p
e
equals last year’s inflation
p
?1
:
p
e
=
p
?1
.
In this case, we can write the Phillips curve as
p
=
p
?1
?
b
(u ? u
n
) +
u
,
which states that inflation depends on past inflation, cyclical unemployment, and
a supply shock.When the Phillips curve is written in this form, the natural rate of
unemployment is sometimes called the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Un-
employment, or NAIRU.
The first term in this form of the Phillips curve,
p
?1
, implies that inflation has
inertia.That is, like an object moving through space, inflation keeps going unless
something acts to stop it. In particular, if unemployment is at the NAIRU and if
there are no supply shocks, the continued rise in price level neither speeds up
nor slows down.This inertia arises because past inflation influences expectations
of future inflation and because these expectations influence the wages and prices
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 361
FYI
The Phillips curve is named after New Zealand–
born economist A. W. Phillips. In 1958 Phillips
observed a negative relationship between the
unemployment rate and the rate of wage infla-
tion in data for the United Kingdom.
9
The
Phillips curve that economists use today differs
in three ways from the relationship Phillips ex-
amined.
First, the modern Phillips curve substitutes
price inflation for wage inflation. This difference
is not crucial, because price inflation and wage
inflation are closely related. In periods when
wages are rising quickly, prices are rising quickly
as well.
The History of the Modern Phillips Curve
Second, the modern Phillips curve includes ex-
pected inflation. This addition is due to the work
of Milton Friedman and Edmund Phelps. In de-
veloping early versions of the imperfect informa-
tion model in the 1960s, these two economists
emphasized the importance of expectations for
aggregate supply.
Third, the modern Phillips curve includes sup-
ply shocks. Credit for this addition goes to
OPEC, the Organization of Petroleum Exporting
Countries. In the 1970s OPEC caused large in-
creases in the world price of oil, which made
economists more aware of the importance of
shocks to aggregate supply.
9
A.W. Phillips,“The Relationship Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money
Wages in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957,’’ Economica 25 (November 1958): 283–299.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 362:27769#/eps at 100%*27769* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:56 AM
that people set. Robert Solow captured the concept of inflation inertia well
when, during the high inflation of the 1970s, he wrote,“Why is our money ever
less valuable? Perhaps it is simply that we have inflation because we expect infla-
tion, and we expect inflation because we’ve had it.’’
In the model of aggregate supply and aggregate demand, inflation inertia is in-
terpreted as persistent upward shifts in both the aggregate supply curve and the
aggregate demand curve. Consider first aggregate supply. If prices have been ris-
ing quickly, people will expect them to continue to rise quickly. Because the po-
sition of the short-run aggregate supply curve depends on the expected price
level, the short-run aggregate supply curve will shift upward over time. It will
continue to shift upward until some event, such as a recession or a supply shock,
changes inflation and thereby changes expectations of inflation.
The aggregate demand curve must also shift upward to confirm the expecta-
tions of inflation. Most often, the continued rise in aggregate demand is caused
by persistent growth in the money supply. If the Fed suddenly halted money
growth, aggregate demand would stabilize, and the upward shift in aggregate
supply would cause a recession.The high unemployment in the recession would
reduce inflation and expected inflation, causing inflation inertia to subside.
Two Causes of Rising and Falling Inflation
The second and third terms in the Phillips curve equation show the two forces
that can change the rate of inflation.
The second term,
b
(u ? u
n
), shows that cyclical unemployment—the devia-
tion of unemployment from its natural rate—exerts upward or downward pres-
sure on inflation. Low unemployment pulls the inflation rate up. This is called
demand-pull inflation because high aggregate demand is responsible for this
type of inflation. High unemployment pulls the inflation rate down.The parame-
ter
b
measures how responsive inflation is to cyclical unemployment.
The third term,
u
, shows that inflation also rises and falls because of supply
shocks. An adverse supply shock, such as the rise in world oil prices in the
1970s, implies a positive value of
u
and causes inflation to rise.This is called
cost-push inflation because adverse supply shocks are typically events that
push up the costs of production.A beneficial supply shock, such as the oil glut
that led to a fall in oil prices in the 1980s, makes
u
negative and causes infla-
tion to fall.
362 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
CASE STUDY
Inflation and Unemployment in the United States
Because inflation and unemployment are such important measures of economic
performance, macroeconomic developments are often viewed through the lens
of the Phillips curve. Figure 13-5 displays the history of inflation and unemploy-
ment in the United States since 1961.These four decades of data illustrate some
of the causes of rising or falling inflation.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 363:27770#/eps at 100%*27770* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 363
The 1960s showed how policymakers can, in the short run, lower unemploy-
ment at the cost of higher inflation.The tax cut of 1964, together with expansion-
ary monetary policy, expanded aggregate demand and pushed the unemployment
rate below 5 percent.This expansion of aggregate demand continued in the late
1960s largely as a by-product of government spending for the Vietnam War. Un-
employment fell lower and inflation rose higher than policymakers intended.
The 1970s were a period of economic turmoil.The decade began with poli-
cymakers trying to lower the inflation inherited from the 1960s. President Nixon
imposed temporary controls on wages and prices, and the Federal Reserve engi-
neered a recession through contractionary monetary policy, but the inflation rate
fell only slightly.The effects of wage and price controls ended when the controls
were lifted, and the recession was too small to counteract the inflationary impact
of the boom that had preceded it. By 1972 the unemployment rate was the same
as a decade earlier, whereas inflation was 3 percentage points higher.
Beginning in 1973 policymakers had to cope with the large supply shocks caused
by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). OPEC first raised
oil prices in the mid-1970s, pushing the inflation rate up to about 10 percent.This
adverse supply shock, together with temporarily tight monetary policy, led to a re-
cession in 1975. High unemployment during the recession reduced inflation some-
what, but further OPEC price hikes pushed inflation up again in the late 1970s.
figure 13-5
Unemployment (percent)
10
8
6
4
2
0
246810
69
70
89
90
91
87
86
92
93
94
95
9697
98
99
00
85
84 83
82
88
71
72
73
74
79
80
81
75
76
77
78
68
66
67
65
64
63
62
61
Inflation
(percent)
Inflation and Unemployment in the United States Since 1961 This figure uses annual
data on the unemployment rate and the inflation rate (percentage change in the GDP
deflator) to illustrate macroeconomic developments over the past four decades.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. Department of Labor.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 364:27771#/eps at 100%*27771* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
The Short-Run Tradeoff Between
Inflation and Unemployment
Consider the options the Phillips curve gives to a policymaker who can influ-
ence aggregate demand with monetary or fiscal policy.At any moment, expected
inflation and supply shocks are beyond the policymaker’s immediate control.Yet,
by changing aggregate demand, the policymaker can alter output, unemploy-
ment, and inflation.The policymaker can expand aggregate demand to lower un-
employment and raise inflation. Or the policymaker can depress aggregate
demand to raise unemployment and lower inflation.
Figure 13-6 plots the Phillips curve equation and shows the short-run
tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.When unemployment is at its
natural rate (u = u
n
), inflation depends on expected inflation and the supply
shock (
p
=
p
e
+
u
).The parameter
b
determines the slope of the tradeoff be-
tween inflation and unemployment. In the short run, for a given level of ex-
pected inflation, policymakers can manipulate aggregate demand to choose a
364 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
The 1980s began with high inflation and high expectations of inflation.
Under the leadership of Chairman Paul Volcker, the Federal Reserve doggedly
pursued monetary policies aimed at reducing inflation. In 1982 and 1983 the un-
employment rate reached its highest level in 40 years. High unemployment,
aided by a fall in oil prices in 1986, pulled the inflation rate down from about 10
percent to about 3 percent. By 1987 the unemployment rate of about 6 percent
was close to most estimates of the natural rate. Unemployment continued to fall
through the 1980s, however, reaching a low of 5.2 percent in 1989 and begin-
ning a new round of demand-pull inflation.
Compared to the previous 30 years, the 1990s were relatively quiet. The
decade began with a recession caused by several contractionary shocks to aggre-
gate demand: tight monetary policy, the savings-and-loan crisis, and a fall in con-
sumer confidence coinciding with the Gulf War.The unemployment rate rose to
7.3 percent in 1992. Inflation fell, but only slightly. Unlike in the 1982 recession,
unemployment in the 1990 recession was never far above the natural rate, so the
effect on inflation was small.
By the late 1990s, inflation and unemployment both reached their lowest lev-
els in many years. Some economists explain this fortunate development by
claiming that the economy’s natural rate of unemployment fell (for reasons dis-
cussed in Chapter 6). Others argue that various temporary factors (such as a
strong U.S. dollar attributable to a financial crisis in Asia) yielded favorable supply
shocks. Most likely, a combination of events helped keep inflation in check, de-
spite low unemployment. In 2000, however, inflation did begin to creep up.
Thus, U.S. macroeconomic history exhibits the many causes of inflation.The
1960s and the 1980s show the two sides of demand-pull inflation: in the 1960s
low unemployment pulled inflation up, and in the 1980s high unemployment
pulled inflation down.The 1970s with their oil-price hikes show the effects of
cost-push inflation.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 365:27772#/eps at 100%*27772* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
combination of inflation and unemployment on this curve, called the short-run
Phillips curve.
Notice that the position of the short-run Phillips curve depends on the ex-
pected rate of inflation. If expected inflation rises, the curve shifts upward, and
the policymaker’s tradeoff becomes less favorable: inflation is higher for any
level of unemployment. Figure 13-7 shows how the tradeoff depends on ex-
pected inflation.
Because people adjust their expectations of inflation over time, the tradeoff be-
tween inflation and unemployment holds only in the short run.The policymaker
cannot keep inflation above expected inflation (and thus unemployment below its
natural rate) forever. Eventually, expectations adapt to whatever inflation rate the
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 365
figure 13-6
Inflation, p
Unemployment, u
p
e
H11001
y
b
1
u
n
The Short-Run Tradeoff Between
Inflation and Unemployment In the
short run, inflation and unemployment
are negatively related. At any point in
time, a policymaker who controls
aggregate demand can choose a
combination of inflation and
unemployment on this short-run
Phillips curve.
figure 13-7
Inflation, p
Unemployment, u
Low
expected
inflation
High
expected
inflation
u
n
Shifts in the Short-Run Tradeoff
The short-run tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment
depends on expected inflation.
The curve is higher when expected
inflation is higher.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 366:27773#/eps at 100%*27773* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
policymaker has chosen. In the long run, the classical dichotomy holds, unem-
ployment returns to its natural rate, and there is no tradeoff between inflation and
unemployment.
Disinflation and the Sacrifice Ratio
Imagine an economy in which unemployment is at its natural rate and inflation
is running at 6 percent.What would happen to unemployment and output if the
central bank pursued a policy to reduce inflation from 6 to 2 percent?
The Phillips curve shows that in the absence of a beneficial supply shock, low-
ering inflation requires a period of high unemployment and reduced output. But
by how much and for how long would unemployment need to rise above the
natural rate? Before deciding whether to reduce inflation, policymakers must
know how much output would be lost during the transition to lower inflation.
This cost can then be compared with the benefits of lower inflation.
366 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
FYI
If you ask an astronomer how far a particular
star is from our sun, he’ll give you a number, but
it won’t be accurate. Man’s ability to measure as-
tronomical distances is still limited. An as-
tronomer might well take better measurements
and conclude that a star is really twice or half as
far away as he previously thought.
Estimates of the natural rate of unemploy-
ment, or NAIRU, are also far from precise. One
problem is supply shocks. Shocks to oil sup-
plies, farm harvests, or technological progress
can cause inflation to rise or fall in the short
run. When we observe rising inflation, therefore,
we cannot be sure if it is evidence that the un-
employment rate is below the natural rate or
evidence that the economy is experiencing an
adverse supply shock.
A second problem is that the natural rate
changes over time. Demographic changes (such
as the aging of the baby-boom generation), pol-
icy changes (such as minimum-wage laws), and
institutional changes (such as the declining role
How Precise Are Estimates of the Natural Rate
of Unemployment?
of unions) all influence the economy’s normal
level of unemployment. Estimating the natural
rate is like hitting a moving target.
Economists deal with these problems using
statistical techniques that yield a best guess
about the natural rate and allow them to gauge
the uncertainty associated with their estimates.
In one such study, Douglas Staiger, James
Stock, and Mark Watson estimated the natural
rate to be 6.2 percent in 1990, with a 95-
percent confidence interval from 5.1 to 7.7 per-
cent. A 95-percent confidence interval is a range
such that the statistician is 95-percent confi-
dent that the true value falls in that range. The
large confidence interval here of 2.6 percentage
points shows that estimates of the natural rate
are not at all precise.
This conclusion has profound implications.
Policymakers may want to keep unemployment
close to its natural rate, but their ability to do so
is limited by the fact that we cannot be sure what
that natural rate is.
10
10
Douglas Staiger, James H. Stock, and Mark W.Watson,“How Precise Are Estimates of the Natural
Rate of Unemployment?” in Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds., Reducing Inflation: Mo-
tivation and Strategy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997).
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 367:27774#/eps at 100%*27774* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
Much research has used the available data to examine the Phillips curve quan-
titatively.The results of these studies are often summarized in a number called the
sacrifice ratio, the percentage of a year’s real GDP that must be forgone to re-
duce inflation by 1 percentage point. Although estimates of the sacrifice ratio
vary substantially, a typical estimate is about 5: for every percentage point that in-
flation is to fall, 5 percent of one year’s GDP must be sacrificed.
11
We can also express the sacrifice ratio in terms of unemployment. Okun’s
law says that a change of 1 percentage point in the unemployment rate trans-
lates into a change of 2 percentage points in GDP.Therefore, reducing infla-
tion by 1 percentage point requires about 2.5 percentage points of cyclical
unemployment.
We can use the sacrifice ratio to estimate by how much and for how long
unemployment must rise to reduce inflation. If reducing inflation by 1 percent-
age point requires a sacrifice of 5 percent of a year’s GDP, reducing inflation by
4 percentage points requires a sacrifice of 20 percent of a year’s GDP. Equiva-
lently, this reduction in inflation requires a sacrifice of 10 percentage points of
cyclical unemployment.
This disinflation could take various forms, each totaling the same sacrifice
of 20 percent of a year’s GDP. For example, a rapid disinflation would lower
output by 10 percent for 2 years: this is sometimes called the cold-turkey solu-
tion to inflation.A moderate disinflation would lower output by 5 percent for
4 years.An even more gradual disinflation would depress output by 2 percent
for a decade.
Rational Expectations and the Possibility
of Painless Disinflation
Because the expectation of inflation influences the short-run tradeoff between
inflation and unemployment, it is crucial to understand how people form expec-
tations. So far, we have been assuming that expected inflation depends on re-
cently observed inflation. Although this assumption of adaptive expectations is
plausible, it is probably too simple to apply in all circumstances.
An alternative approach is to assume that people have rational expectations.
That is, we might assume that people optimally use all the available information,
including information about current government policies, to forecast the future.
Because monetary and fiscal policies influence inflation, expected inflation
should also depend on the monetary and fiscal policies in effect. According to
the theory of rational expectations, a change in monetary or fiscal policy will
change expectations, and an evaluation of any policy change must incorporate
this effect on expectations. If people do form their expectations rationally, then
inflation may have less inertia than it first appears.
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 367
11
Arthur M. Okun,“Efficient Disinflationary Policies,’’ American Economic Review 68 (May 1978):
348–352; and Robert J. Gordon and Stephen R. King,“The Output Cost of Disinflation in Tradi-
tional and Vector Autoregressive Models,’’ Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1982:1): 205–245.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 368:27775#/eps at 100%*27775* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
Here is how Thomas Sargent, a prominent advocate of rational expectations,
describes its implications for the Phillips curve:
An alternative “rational expectations’’ view denies that there is any inherent mo-
mentum to the present process of inflation.This view maintains that firms and work-
ers have now come to expect high rates of inflation in the future and that they strike
inflationary bargains in light of these expectations. However, it is held that people ex-
pect high rates of inflation in the future precisely because the government’s current
and prospective monetary and fiscal policies warrant those expectations....Thus infla-
tion only seems to have a momentum of its own; it is actually the long-term govern-
ment policy of persistently running large deficits and creating money at high rates
which imparts the momentum to the inflation rate.An implication of this view is that
inflation can be stopped much more quickly than advocates of the “momentum’’ view
have indicated and that their estimates of the length of time and the costs of stopping
inflation in terms of foregone output are erroneous. . . . [Stopping inflation] would re-
quire a change in the policy regime:there must be an abrupt change in the continuing
government policy, or strategy, for setting deficits now and in the future that is suffi-
ciently binding as to be widely believed. . . . How costly such a move would be in
terms of foregone output and how long it would be in taking effect would depend
partly on how resolute and evident the government’s commitment was.
12
Thus, advocates of rational expectations argue that the short-run Phillips
curve does not accurately represent the options that policymakers have available.
They believe that if policymakers are credibly committed to reducing inflation,
rational people will understand the commitment and will quickly lower their ex-
pectations of inflation. Inflation can then come down without a rise in unem-
ployment and fall in output. According to the theory of rational expectations,
traditional estimates of the sacrifice ratio are not useful for evaluating the impact
of alternative policies. Under a credible policy, the costs of reducing inflation
may be much lower than estimates of the sacrifice ratio suggest.
In the most extreme case, one can imagine reducing the rate of inflation with-
out causing any recession at all.A painless disinflation has two requirements. First,
the plan to reduce inflation must be announced before the workers and firms
who set wages and prices have formed their expectations. Second, the workers
and firms must believe the announcement; otherwise, they will not reduce their
expectations of inflation. If both requirements are met, the announcement will
immediately shift the short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment
downward, permitting a lower rate of inflation without higher unemployment.
Although the rational-expectations approach remains controversial, almost all
economists agree that expectations of inflation influence the short-run tradeoff
between inflation and unemployment.The credibility of a policy to reduce infla-
tion is therefore one determinant of how costly the policy will be. Unfortunately,
it is often difficult to predict whether the public will view the announcement of a
new policy as credible.The central role of expectations makes forecasting the re-
sults of alternative policies far more difficult.
368 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
12
Thomas J. Sargent,“The Ends of Four Big Inflations,’’ in Robert E. Hall, ed., Inflation: Causes and
Effects (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982).
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 369:27776#/eps at 100%*27776* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 369
CASE STUDY
The Sacrifice Ratio in Practice
The Phillips curve with adaptive expectations implies that reducing inflation re-
quires a period of high unemployment and low output. By contrast, the rational-
expectations approach suggests that reducing inflation can be much less costly.
What happens during actual disinflations?
Consider the U.S. disinflation in the early 1980s.This decade began with some
of the highest rates of inflation in U.S. history.Yet because of the tight monetary
policies the Fed pursued under Chairman Paul Volcker, the rate of inflation fell
substantially in the first few years of the decade.This episode provides a natural
experiment with which to estimate how much output is lost during the process
of disinflation.
The first question is, how much did inflation fall? As measured by the GDP
deflator, inflation reached a peak of 9.7 percent in 1981. It is natural to end the
episode in 1985 because oil prices plunged in 1986—a large, beneficial supply
shock unrelated to Fed policy. In 1985, inflation was 3.0 percent, so we can esti-
mate that the Fed engineered a reduction in inflation of 6.7 percentage points
over four years.
The second question is, how much output was lost during this period? Table
13-1 shows the unemployment rate from 1982 to 1985.Assuming that the nat-
ural rate of unemployment was 6 percent, we can compute the amount of cycli-
cal unemployment in each year. In total over this period, there were 9.5
percentage points of cyclical unemployment. Okun’s law says that 1 percentage
point of unemployment translates into 2 percentage points of GDP. Therefore,
19.0 percentage points of annual GDP were lost during the disinflation.
Unemployment Natural Cyclical
Year Rate, u Rate, u
n
Unemployment, u ? u
n
1982 9.5% 6.0% 3.5%
1983 9.5 6.0 3.5
1984 7.4 6.0 1.4
1985 7.1 6.0 1.1
Total 9.5%
Unemployment During the Volcker Disinflation
table 13-1
Now we can compute the sacrifice ratio for this episode.We know that 19.0
percentage points of GDP were lost and that inflation fell by 6.7 percentage
points. Hence, 19.0/6.7, or 2.8, percentage points of GDP were lost for each
percentage-point reduction in inflation.The estimate of the sacrifice ratio from
the Volcker disinflation is 2.8.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 370:27777#/eps at 100%*27777* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
370 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
This estimate of the sacrifice ratio is smaller than the estimates made before
Volcker was appointed Fed chairman. In other words,Volcker reduced inflation
at a smaller cost than many economists had predicted. One explanation is that
Volcker’s tough stand was credible enough to influence expectations of inflation
directly.Yet the change in expectations was not large enough to make the disin-
flation painless: in 1982 unemployment reached its highest level since the Great
Depression.
Although the Volcker disinflation is only one historical episode, this kind of
analysis can be applied to other disinflations.A recent study documented the re-
sults of 65 disinflations in 19 countries. In almost all cases, the reduction in infla-
tion came at the cost of temporarily lower output.Yet the size of the output loss
varied from episode to episode. Rapid disinflations usually had smaller sacrifice
ratios than slower ones.That is, in contrast to what the Phillips curve with adap-
tive expectations suggests, a cold-turkey approach appears less costly than a grad-
ual one. Moreover, countries with more flexible wage-setting institutions, such as
shorter labor contracts, had smaller sacrifice ratios. These findings indicate that
reducing inflation always has some cost, but that policies and institutions can af-
fect its magnitude.
13
13
Laurence Ball, “What Determines the Sacrifice Ratio?” in N. Gregory Mankiw, ed., Monetary
Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994).
Hysteresis and the Challenge to the Natural-Rate
Hypothesis
Our discussion of the cost of disinflation—and indeed our entire discussion of
economic fluctuations in the past four chapters—has been based on an assump-
tion called the natural-rate hypothesis.This hypothesis is summarized in the
following statement:
Fluctuations in aggregate demand affect output and employment only in the short run. In the
long run, the economy returns to the levels of output, employment, and unemployment de-
scribed by the classical model.
The natural-rate hypothesis allows macroeconomists to study separately short-
run and long-run developments in the economy. It is one expression of the clas-
sical dichotomy.
Recently, some economists have challenged the natural-rate hypothesis by
suggesting that aggregate demand may affect output and employment even in
the long run.They have pointed out a number of mechanisms through which re-
cessions might leave permanent scars on the economy by altering the natural rate
of unemployment. Hysteresis is the term used to describe the long-lasting in-
fluence of history on the natural rate.
A recession can have permanent effects if it changes the people who be-
come unemployed. For instance, workers might lose valuable job skills when
unemployed, lowering their ability to find a job even after the recession ends.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 371:27778#/eps at 100%*27778* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
Alternatively, a long period of unemployment may change an individual’s atti-
tude toward work and reduce his desire to find employment. In either case, the
recession permanently inhibits the process of job search and raises the amount
of frictional unemployment.
Another way in which a recession can permanently affect the economy is by
changing the process that determines wages. Those who become unemployed
may lose their influence on the wage-setting process. Unemployed workers may
lose their status as union members, for example. More generally, some of the in-
siders in the wage-setting process become outsiders. If the smaller group of insiders
cares more about high real wages and less about high employment, then the re-
cession may permanently push real wages further above the equilibrium level
and raise the amount of structural unemployment.
Hysteresis remains a controversial theory. Some economists believe the theory
helps explain persistently high unemployment in Europe, because the rise in Eu-
ropean unemployment starting in the early 1980s coincided with disinflation but
continued after inflation stabilized. Moreover, the increase in unemployment
tended to be larger for those countries that experienced the greatest reductions
in inflations, such as Ireland, Italy, and Spain. Yet there is still no consensus
whether the hysteresis phenomenon is significant, or why it might be more pro-
nounced in some countries than in others. (Other explanations of high Euro-
pean unemployment, discussed in Chapter 6, give little role to the disinflation.) If
it is true, however, the theory is important, because hysteresis greatly increases the
cost of recessions. Put another way, hysteresis raises the sacrifice ratio, because
output is lost even after the period of disinflation is over.
14
13-3 Conclusion
We began this chapter by discussing three models of aggregate supply, each of
which focuses on a different reason why the short-run aggregate supply curve is
upward sloping. The three models have similar predictions for the aggregate
economy, and all of them yield a short-run tradeoff between inflation and un-
employment. A convenient way to express and analyze that tradeoff is with the
Phillips curve equation, according to which inflation depends on expected infla-
tion, cyclical unemployment, and supply shocks.
Keep in mind that not all economists endorse all the ideas discussed here.
There is widespread disagreement, for instance, about the practical importance of
rational expectations and the relevance of hysteresis. If you find it difficult to fit
all the pieces together, you are not alone.The study of aggregate supply remains
one of the most unsettled—and therefore one of the most exciting—research
areas in macroeconomics.
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 371
14
Olivier J. Blanchard and Lawrence H. Summers,“Beyond the Natural Rate Hypothesis,’’ Ameri-
can Economic Review 78 (May 1988): 182–187; Laurence Ball, “Disinflation and the NAIRU,” in
Christina D. Romer and David H. Romer, eds., Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy (Chicago:
University of Chicago Press, 1997): 167–185.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 372:27779#/eps at 100%*27779* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
Summary
1. The three theories of aggregate supply—the sticky-wage, imperfect-informa-
tion, and sticky-price models—attribute deviations of output and employ-
ment from the natural rate to various market imperfections.According to all
three theories, output rises above the natural rate when the price level ex-
ceeds the expected price level, and output falls below the natural rate when
the price level is less than the expected price level.
2. Economists often express aggregate supply in a relationship called the Phillips
curve.The Phillips curve says that inflation depends on expected inflation, the
deviation of unemployment from its natural rate, and supply shocks.Accord-
ing to the Phillips curve, policymakers who control aggregate demand face a
short-run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment.
3. If expected inflation depends on recently observed inflation, then inflation
has inertia, which means that reducing inflation requires either a beneficial
supply shock or a period of high unemployment and reduced output. If peo-
ple have rational expectations, however, then a credible announcement of a
change in policy might be able to influence expectations directly and, there-
fore, reduce inflation without causing a recession.
4. Most economists accept the natural-rate hypothesis, according to which fluc-
tuations in aggregate demand have only short-run effects on output and un-
employment.Yet some economists have suggested ways in which recessions
can leave permanent scars on the economy by raising the natural rate of un-
employment.
372 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
1. Explain the three theories of aggregate supply.
On what market imperfection does each theory
rely? What do the theories have in common?
2. How is the Phillips curve related to aggregate
supply?
3. Why might inflation be inertial?
KEY CONCEPTS
Sticky-wage model
Imperfect-information model
Sticky-price model
Phillips curve
QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW
Adaptive expectations
Demand-pull inflation
Cost-push inflation
Sacrifice ratio
Rational expectations
Natural-rate hypothesis
Hysteresis
4. Explain the differences between demand-pull in-
flation and cost-push inflation.
5. Under what circumstances might it be possible to
reduce inflation without causing a recession?
6. Explain two ways in which a recession might
raise the natural rate of unemployment.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 373:27780#/eps at 100%*27780* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 373
PROBLEMS AND APPLICATIONS
1. Consider the following changes in the sticky-
wage model.
a. Suppose that labor contracts specify that the
nominal wage be fully indexed for inflation.
That is, the nominal wage is to be adjusted
to fully compensate for changes in the con-
sumer price index. How does full indexa-
tion alter the aggregate supply curve in this
model?
b. Suppose now that indexation is only partial.
That is, for every increase in the CPI, the
nominal wage rises, but by a smaller percent-
age. How does partial indexation alter the ag-
gregate supply curve in this model?
2. In the sticky-price model, describe the aggregate
supply curve in the following special cases. How
do these cases compare to the short-run aggre-
gate supply curve we discussed in Chapter 9?
a. No firms have flexible prices (s = 1).
b. The desired price does not depend on aggre-
gate output (a = 0).
3. Suppose that an economy has the Phillips curve
p
=
p
?1
? 0.5(u ? 0.06).
a. What is the natural rate of unemployment?
b. Graph the short-run and long-run relation-
ships between inflation and unemployment.
c. How much cyclical unemployment is neces-
sary to reduce inflation by 5 percentage points?
Using Okun’s law, compute the sacrifice ratio.
d. Inflation is running at 10 percent. The Fed
wants to reduce it to 5 percent. Give two sce-
narios that will achieve that goal.
4. According to the rational-expectations approach,
if everyone believes that policymakers are com-
mitted to reducing inflation, the cost of reducing
inflation—the sacrifice ratio—will be lower than
if the public is skeptical about the policymakers’
intentions. Why might this be true? How might
credibility be achieved?
5. Assume that people have rational expectations
and that the economy is described by the sticky-
wage or sticky-price model. Explain why each of
the following propositions is true:
a. Only unanticipated changes in the money sup-
ply affect real GDP. Changes in the money
supply that were anticipated when wages and
prices were set do not have any real effects.
b. If the Fed chooses the money supply at the
same time as people are setting wages and
prices, so that everyone has the same infor-
mation about the state of the economy, then
monetary policy cannot be used systemati-
cally to stabilize output. Hence, a policy of
keeping the money supply constant will have
the same real effects as a policy of adjusting
the money supply in response to the state of
the economy. (This is called the policy irrele-
vance proposition.)
c. If the Fed sets the money supply well after
people have set wages and prices, so the Fed
has collected more information about the state
of the economy, then monetary policy can be
used systematically to stabilize output.
6. Suppose that an economy has the Phillips curve
p
=
p
?1
? 0.5(u ? u
n
),
and that the natural rate of unemployment is
given by an average of the past two years’ unem-
ployment:
u
n
= 0.5(u
?1
+ u
?2
).
a. Why might the natural rate of unemployment
depend on recent unemployment (as is as-
sumed in the preceding equation)?
b. Suppose that the Fed follows a policy to re-
duce permanently the inflation rate by 1 per-
centage point.What effect will that policy have
on the unemployment rate over time?
c. What is the sacrifice ratio in this economy?
Explain.
d. What do these equations imply about the
short-run and long-run tradeoffs between in-
flation and unemployment?
7. Some economists believe that taxes have an im-
portant effect on labor supply. They argue that
higher taxes cause people to want to work less
and that lower taxes cause them to want to work
more. Consider how this effect alters the macro-
economic analysis of tax changes.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 374:27781#/eps at 100%*27781* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
a. If this view is correct, how does a tax cut affect
the natural rate of output?
b. How does a tax cut affect the aggregate de-
mand curve? The long-run aggregate supply
curve? The short-run aggregate supply curve?
c. What is the short-run impact of a tax cut on
output and the price level? How does your an-
swer differ from the case without the labor-
supply effect?
d. What is the long-run impact of a tax cut on
output and the price level? How does your an-
swer differ from the case without the labor-
supply effect?
8. Economist Alan Blinder, whom Bill Clinton ap-
pointed to be Vice Chairman of the Federal Re-
serve, once wrote the following:
The costs that attend the low and moderate inflation
rates experienced in the United States and in other
industrial countries appear to be quite modest—
more like a bad cold than a cancer on society....
As rational individuals, we do not volunteer for a
lobotomy to cure a head cold.Yet, as a collectivity,
we routinely prescribe the economic equivalent of
lobotomy (high unemployment) as a cure for the
inflationary cold.
15
What do you think Blinder meant by this? What
are the policy implications of the viewpoint
Blinder is advocating? Do you agree? Why or
why not?
9. Go to the Web site of the Bureau of Labor Statis-
tics (www.bls.gov). For each of the past five years,
find the inflation rate as measured by the con-
sumer price index (all items) and as measured by
the CPI excluding food and energy. Compare
these two measures of inflation.Why might they
be different? What might the difference tell you
about shifts in the aggregate supply curve and in
the short-run Phillips curve?
374 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
15
Alan Blinder, Hard Heads, Soft Hearts:Tough-Minded Economics for a Just Society (Reading, Mass.:
Addison-Wesley, 1987), 51.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 375:27782#/eps at 100%*27782* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 375
In the previous chapters, we have seen many models of how the economy works.
When learning these models, it can be hard to see how they are related. Now
that we have finished developing the model of aggregate demand and aggregate
supply, this is a good time to look back at what we have learned.This appendix
sketches a large model that incorporates much of the theory we have already
seen, including the classical theory presented in Part II and the business cycle
theory presented in Part IV. The notation and equations should be familiar from
previous chapters.
The model has seven equations:
Y = C(Y ?T ) + I(r) + G + NX(
e
) IS: Goods Market Equilibrium
M/P = L(i,Y ) LM: Money Market Equilibrium
NX(
e
) = CF(r ? r*) Foreign Exchange Market
Equilibrium
i = r +
p
e
Relationship Between Real and
Nominal Interest Rates
e
= eP/P* Relationship Between Real and
Nominal Exchange Rates
Y =Y
?
+
a
(P ? P
e
) Aggregate Supply
Y
?
= F(K
?
,L
?
) Natural Rate of Output
These seven equations determine the equilibrium values of seven endogenous
variables: output Y, the natural rate of output Y
?
, the real interest rate r, the nom-
inal interest rate i, the real exchange rate
e
, the nominal exchange rate e, and the
price level P.
There are many exogenous variables that influence these endogenous vari-
ables. They include the money supply M, government purchases G, taxes T,
the capital stock K, the labor force L, the world price level P*, and the world
real interest rate r*. In addition, there are two expectational variables: the ex-
pectation of future inflation
p
e
and the expectation of the current price level
formed in the past P
e
. As written, the model takes these expectational vari-
ables as exogenous, although additional equations could be added to make
them endogenous.
Although mathematical techniques are available to analyze this seven-equation
model, they are beyond the scope of this book. But this large model is still useful,
because we can use it to see how the smaller models we have examined are related
to one another. In particular, many of the models we have been studying are special cases
of this large model. Let’s consider six special cases.
Special Case 1: The Classical Closed Economy Suppose that P
e
= P, L(i, Y )
= (1/V )Y, and CF(r ? r*) = 0. In words, this means that expectations of the price
A Big, Comprehensive Model
APPENDIX
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 376:27783#/eps at 100%*27783* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
level adjust so that expectations are correct, that money demand is proportional
to income, and that there are no international capital flows. In this case, output is
always at its natural rate, the real interest rate adjusts to equilibrate the goods
market, the price level moves parallel with the money supply, and the nominal
interest rate adjusts one-for-one with expected inflation.This special case corre-
sponds to the economy analyzed in Chapters 3 and 4.
Special Case 2: The Classical Small Open Economy Suppose that P
e
= P,
L(i, Y ) = (1/V )Y, and CF(r ? r*) is infinitely elastic. Now we are examining the
special case when international capital flows respond greatly to any differences
between the domestic and world interest rates.This means that r = r* and that the
trade balance NX equals the difference between saving and investment at the
world interest rate. This special case corresponds to the economy analyzed in
Chapter 5.
Special Case 3: The Basic Model of Aggregate Demand and Aggregate
Supply Suppose that
a
is infinite and L(i, Y ) = (1/V )Y. In this case, the short-
run aggregate supply curve is horizontal, and the aggregate demand curve is de-
termined only by the quantity equation. This special case corresponds to the
economy analyzed in Chapter 9.
Special Case 4: The IS–LM Model Suppose that
a
is infinite and CF(r ? r*) =
0. In this case, the short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal, and there are no
international capital flows. For any given level of expected inflation
p
e
, the level of
income and interest rate must adjust to equilibrate the goods market and the
money market.This special case corresponds to the economy analyzed in Chapter
10 and 11.
Special Case 5: The Mundell–Fleming Model with a Floating Exchange
Rate Suppose that
a
is infinite and CF(r ? r*) is infinitely elastic. In this case, the
short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal, and international capital flows are
so great as to ensure that r = r*.The exchange rate floats freely to reach its equi-
librium level. This special case corresponds to the first economy analyzed in
Chapter 12.
Special Case 6: The Mundell–Fleming Model with a Fixed Exchange Rate
Suppose that
a
is infinite, CF(r ? r*) is infinitely elastic, and e is fixed. In this
case, the short-run aggregate supply curve is horizontal, huge international capi-
tal flows ensure that r = r*, but the exchange rate is set by the central bank.The
exchange rate is now an exogenous policy variable, but the money supply M is
an endogenous variable that must adjust to ensure the exchange rate hits the
fixed level. This special case corresponds to the second economy analyzed in
Chapter 12.
You should now see the value in this big model. Even though the model is too
large to be useful in developing an intuitive understanding of how the economy
works, it shows that the different models we have been studying are closely re-
lated. Each model shows a different facet of the larger and more realistic model
376 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
User JOEWA:Job EFF01429:6264_ch13:Pg 377:27784#/eps at 100%*27784* Mon, Feb 18, 2002 12:57 AM
presented here. In each chapter, we made some simplifying assumptions to make
the big model smaller and easier to understand. When thinking about the real
world, it is important to keep the simplifying assumptions in mind and to draw
on the insights learned in each of the chapters.
CHAPTER 13 Aggregate Supply | 377
1. Let’s consider some more special cases of this
large model. Starting with the large model, what
extra assumptions would you need to yield each
of the following models:
a. The model of the classical large open economy
in the appendix to Chapter 5.
MORE PROBLEMS AND APPLICATIONS
b. The Keynesian cross in the first half of Chapter
10.
c. The IS–LM model for the large open econ-
omy in the appendix to Chapter 12.