User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 236:24782#/eps at 100%*24782* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:07 AM
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 237:27129#/eps at 100%*27129* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:07 AM
part IV
Business Cycle Theory:
The Economy in
the Short Run
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 238:27130#/eps at 100%*27130* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:07 AM
Economic fluctuations present a recurring problem for economists and policy-
makers. This problem is illustrated in Figure 9-1, which shows growth in real
GDP for the U.S. economy. As you can see, although the economy experiences
long-run growth that averages about 3.5 percent per year, this growth is not at all
steady. Recessions—periods of falling incomes and rising unemployment—are
frequent. In the recession of 1990, for instance, real GDP fell 2.2 percent from its
peak to its trough, and the unemployment rate rose to 7.7 percent. During reces-
sions, not only are more people unemployed, but those who are employed have
shorter workweeks, as more workers have to accept part-time jobs and fewer
workers have the opportunity to work overtime.When recessions end and the
economy enters a boom, these effects work in reverse: incomes rise, unemploy-
ment falls, and workweeks expand.
Economists call these short-run fluctuations in output and employment the
business cycle. Although this term suggests that economic fluctuations are regular
and predictable, they are not. Recessions are as irregular as they are common.
Sometimes they are close together, such as the recessions of 1980 and 1982.
Sometimes they are far apart, such as the recessions of 1982 and 1990.
In Parts II and III of this book, we developed theories to explain how the
economy behaves in the long run. Those theories were based on the classical
dichotomy—the premise that real variables, such as output and employment, are
not affected by what happens to nominal variables, such as the money supply and
the price level. Although classical theories are useful for explaining long-run
trends, including the economic growth we observe from decade to decade, most
economists believe that the classical dichotomy does not hold in the short run
and, therefore, that classical theories cannot explain year-to-year fluctuations in
output and employment.
Here, in Part IV, we see how economists explain these short-run fluctuations.
This chapter begins our analysis by discussing the key differences between the
long run and the short run and by introducing the model of aggregate supply
9
Introduction to Economic Fluctuations
CHAPTER
The modern world regards business cycles much as the ancient Egyptians
regarded the overflowing of the Nile.The phenomenon recurs at intervals, it
is of great importance to everyone, and natural causes of it are not in sight.
— John Bates Clark, 1898
NINE
238 |
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 239:27131#/eps at 100%*27131* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:07 AM
and aggregate demand.With this model we can show how shocks to the econ-
omy lead to short-run fluctuations in output and employment.
Just as Egypt now controls the flooding of the Nile Valley with the Aswan
Dam, modern society tries to control the business cycle with appropriate eco-
nomic policies.The model we develop over the next several chapters shows how
monetary and fiscal policies influence the business cycle.We will see that these
policies can potentially stabilize the economy or, if poorly conducted, make the
problem of economic instability even worse.
9-1 Time Horizons in Macroeconomics
Before we start building a model of short-run economic fluctuations, let’s step
back and ask a fundamental question:Why do economists need different models
for different time horizons? Why can’t we stop the course here and be content
with the classical models developed in Chapters 3 through 8? The answer, as this
book has consistently reminded its reader, is that classical macroeconomic theory
applies to the long run but not to the short run. But why is this so?
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 239
figure 9-1
Percentage
change from
4 quarters
earlier
10
8
6
4
2
0
H110022
H110024
1960 1965
Year
1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000
Real GDP growth rate
Average growth rate
Real GDP Growth in the United States Growth in real GDP averages about 3.5 percent per
year, as indicated by the orange line, but there are substantial fluctuations around this
average. Recessions are periods when the production of goods and services is declining,
represented here by negative growth in real GDP.
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 240:27132#/eps at 100%*27132* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
How the Short Run and Long Run Differ
Most macroeconomists believe that the key difference between the short run and
the long run is the behavior of prices. In the long run, prices are flexible and can re-
spond to changes in supply or demand. In the short run, many prices are “sticky’’ at some
predetermined level. Because prices behave differently in the short run than in the
long run, economic policies have different effects over different time horizons.
To see how the short run and the long run differ, consider the effects of a
change in monetary policy. Suppose that the Federal Reserve suddenly reduced
the money supply by 5 percent. According to the classical model, which almost
all economists agree describes the economy in the long run, the money supply
affects nominal variables—variables measured in terms of money—but not real
variables. In the long run, a 5-percent reduction in the money supply lowers all
prices (including nominal wages) by 5 percent whereas all real variables remain
the same.Thus, in the long run, changes in the money supply do not cause fluc-
tuations in output or employment.
In the short run, however, many prices do not respond to changes in mone-
tary policy. A reduction in the money supply does not immediately cause all
firms to cut the wages they pay, all stores to change the price tags on their goods,
all mail-order firms to issue new catalogs, and all restaurants to print new menus.
Instead, there is little immediate change in many prices; that is, many prices are
sticky. This short-run price stickiness implies that the short-run impact of a
change in the money supply is not the same as the long-run impact.
A model of economic fluctuations must take into account this short-run price
stickiness. We will see that the failure of prices to adjust quickly and completely
means that, in the short run, output and employment must do some of the adjusting
instead. In other words, during the time horizon over which prices are sticky, the
classical dichotomy no longer holds: nominal variables can influence real variables,
and the economy can deviate from the equilibrium predicted by the classical model.
240 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
CASE STUDY
The Puzzle of Sticky Magazine Prices
How sticky are prices? The answer to this question depends on what price we
consider. Some commodities, such as wheat, soybeans, and pork bellies, are traded
on organized exchanges, and their prices change every minute. No one would
call these prices sticky.Yet the prices of most goods and services change much
less frequently. One survey found that 39 percent of firms change their prices
once a year, and another 10 percent change their prices less than once a year.
1
The reasons for price stickiness are not always apparent. Consider, for example,
the market for magazines. A study has documented that magazines change their
newsstand prices very infrequently. The typical magazine allows inflation to erode
1
Alan S. Blinder,“On Sticky Prices:Academic Theories Meet the Real World,’’ in N. G. Mankiw,
ed., Monetary Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994): 117–154.A case study in Chap-
ter 19 discusses this survey in more detail.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 241:27133#/eps at 100%*27133* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
The Model of Aggregate Supply
and Aggregate Demand
How does introducing sticky prices change our view of how the economy works?
We can answer this question by considering economists’ two favorite words—
supply and demand.
In classical macroeconomic theory, the amount of output depends on the
economy’s ability to supply goods and services, which in turn depends on the
supplies of capital and labor and on the available production technology.This is
the essence of the basic classical model in Chapter 3, as well as of the Solow
growth model in Chapters 7 and 8. Flexible prices are a crucial assumption of
classical theory.The theory posits, sometimes implicitly, that prices adjust to en-
sure that the quantity of output demanded equals the quantity supplied.
The economy works quite differently when prices are sticky. In this case, as we
will see, output also depends on the demand for goods and services. Demand, in
turn, is influenced by monetary policy, fiscal policy, and various other factors. Be-
cause monetary and fiscal policy can influence the economy’s output over the
time horizon when prices are sticky, price stickiness provides a rationale for why
these policies may be useful in stabilizing the economy in the short run.
In the rest of this chapter, we develop a model that makes these ideas more pre-
cise.The model of supply and demand, which we used in Chapter 1 to discuss the
market for pizza, offers some of the most fundamental insights in economics.This
model shows how the supply and demand for any good jointly determine the
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 241
its real price by about 25 percent before it raises its nominal price.When inflation
is 4 percent per year, the typical magazine changes its price about every six years.
2
Why do magazines keep their prices the same for so long? Economists do not
have a definitive answer.The question is puzzling because it would seem that for
magazines, the cost of a price change is small.To change prices, a mail-order firm
must issue a new catalog and a restaurant must print a new menu, but a magazine
publisher can simply print a new price on the cover of the next issue. Perhaps the
cost to the publisher of charging the wrong price is also small. Or maybe cus-
tomers would find it inconvenient if the price of their favorite magazine
changed every month.
As the magazine example shows, explaining at the microeconomic level why
prices are sticky is sometimes hard.The cause of price stickiness is, therefore, an
active area of research, which we discuss more fully in Chapter 19. In this chap-
ter, however, we simply assume that prices are sticky so we can start developing
the link between sticky prices and the business cycle.Although not yet fully ex-
plained, short-run price stickiness is widely believed to be crucial for under-
standing short-run economic fluctuations.
2
Stephen G. Cecchetti,“The Frequency of Price Adjustment:A Study of the Newsstand Prices of
Magazines,’’ Journal of Econometrics 31 (1986): 255–274.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 242:27134#/eps at 100%*27134* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
good’s price and the quantity sold, and how shifts in supply and demand affect the
price and quantity. In the rest of this chapter, we introduce the “economy-size’’
version of this model—the model of aggregate supply and aggregate demand. This
macroeconomic model allows us to study how the aggregate price level and the
quantity of aggregate output are determined. It also provides a way to contrast
how the economy behaves in the long run and how it behaves in the short run.
Although the model of aggregate supply and aggregate demand resembles the
model of supply and demand for a single good, the analogy is not exact. The
model of supply and demand for a single good considers only one good within a
large economy. By contrast, as we will see in the coming chapters, the model of
aggregate supply and aggregate demand is a sophisticated model that incorpo-
rates the interactions among many markets.
9-2 Aggregate Demand
Aggregate demand (AD) is the relationship between the quantity of output
demanded and the aggregate price level. In other words, the aggregate demand
curve tells us the quantity of goods and services people want to buy at any given
level of prices.We examine the theory of aggregate demand in detail in Chapters
10 through 12. Here we use the quantity theory of money to provide a simple,
although incomplete, derivation of the aggregate demand curve.
The Quantity Equation as Aggregate Demand
Recall from Chapter 4 that the quantity theory says that
MV = PY,
where M is the money supply, V is the velocity of money, P is the price level, and
Y is the amount of output. If the velocity of money is constant, then this equa-
tion states that the money supply determines the nominal value of output, which
in turn is the product of the price level and the amount of output.
You might recall that the quantity equation can be rewritten in terms of the
supply and demand for real money balances:
M/P = (M/P)
d
= kY,
where k = 1/V is a parameter determining how much money people want to
hold for every dollar of income. In this form, the quantity equation states that the
supply of real money balances M/P equals the demand (M/P)
d
and that the de-
mand is proportional to output Y.The velocity of money V is the “flip side” of
the money demand parameter k.
For any fixed money supply and velocity, the quantity equation yields a nega-
tive relationship between the price level P and output Y. Figure 9-2 graphs the
combinations of P and Y that satisfy the quantity equation holding M and V
constant.This downward-sloping curve is called the aggregate demand curve.
242 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 243:27135#/eps at 100%*27135* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
Why the Aggregate Demand Curve Slopes Downward
As a strictly mathematical matter, the quantity equation explains the downward
slope of the aggregate demand curve very simply.The money supply M and the
velocity of money V determine the nominal value of output PY. Once PY is
fixed, if P goes up, Y must go down.
What is the economics that lies behind this mathematical relationship? For a
complete answer, we have to wait for a couple of chapters. For now, however,
consider the following logic: Because we have assumed the velocity of money is
fixed, the money supply determines the dollar value of all transactions in the
economy. (This conclusion should be familiar from Chapter 4.) If the price level
rises, each transaction requires more dollars, so the number of transactions and
thus the quantity of goods and services purchased must fall.
We can also explain the downward slope of the aggregate demand curve by
thinking about the supply and demand for real money balances. If output is
higher, people engage in more transactions and need higher real balances M/P.
For a fixed money supply M, higher real balances imply a lower price level. Con-
versely, if the price level is lower, real money balances are higher; the higher level
of real balances allows a greater volume of transactions, which means a greater
quantity of output is demanded.
Shifts in the Aggregate Demand Curve
The aggregate demand curve is drawn for a fixed value of the money supply. In
other words, it tells us the possible combinations of P and Y for a given value of
M. If the Fed changes the money supply, then the possible combinations of P and
Y change, which means the aggregate demand curve shifts.
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 243
figure 9-2
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
Aggregate
demand,
AD
The Aggregate Demand Curve
The aggregate demand curve AD
shows the relationship between
the price level P and the quantity
of goods and services demanded
Y. It is drawn for a given value of
the money supply M. The aggre-
gate demand curve slopes down-
ward: the higher the price level P,
the lower the level of real balances
M/P, and therefore the lower the
quantity of goods and services
demanded Y.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 244:27136#/eps at 100%*27136* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
For example, consider what happens if the Fed reduces the money supply.The
quantity equation, MV = PY, tells us that the reduction in the money supply
leads to a proportionate reduction in the nominal value of output PY. For any
given price level, the amount of output is lower, and for any given amount of
output, the price level is lower.As in Figure 9-3(a), the aggregate demand curve
relating P and Y shifts inward.
244 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 9-3
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
(a) Inward Shifts in the Aggregate Demand Curve
AD
2
AD
1
Reductions in the
money supply shift
the aggregate demand
curve to the left.
Shifts in the Aggregate Demand
Curve Changes in the money
supply shift the aggregate de-
mand curve. In panel (a), a de-
crease in the money supply M
reduces the nominal value of
output PY. For any given price
level P, output Y is lower. Thus,
a decrease in the money supply
shifts the aggregate demand
curve inward from AD
1
to AD
2
.
In panel (b), an increase in the
money supply M raises the nomi-
nal value of output PY. For any
given price level P, output Y is
higher. Thus, an increase in the
money supply shifts the aggre-
gate demand curve outward
from AD
1
to AD
2
.
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
(b) Outward Shifts in the Aggregate Demand Curve
Increases in the
money supply shift
the aggregate demand
curve to the right.
AD
1
AD
2
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 245:27137#/eps at 100%*27137* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
The opposite occurs if the Fed increases the money supply. The quantity
equation tells us that an increase in M leads to an increase in PY. For any given
price level, the amount of output is higher, and for any given amount of output,
the price level is higher.As shown in Figure 9-3(b), the aggregate demand curve
shifts outward.
Fluctuations in the money supply are not the only source of fluctuations in
aggregate demand. Even if the money supply is held constant, the aggregate de-
mand curve shifts if some event causes a change in the velocity of money. Over
the next three chapters, we consider many possible reasons for shifts in the aggre-
gate demand curve.
9-3 Aggregate Supply
By itself, the aggregate demand curve does not tell us the price level or the
amount of output; it merely gives a relationship between these two variables.To
accompany the aggregate demand curve, we need another relationship between
P and Y that crosses the aggregate demand curve—an aggregate supply curve.
The aggregate demand and aggregate supply curves together pin down the
economy’s price level and quantity of output.
Aggregate supply (AS) is the relationship between the quantity of goods
and services supplied and the price level. Because the firms that supply goods and
services have flexible prices in the long run but sticky prices in the short run, the
aggregate supply relationship depends on the time horizon.We need to discuss
two different aggregate supply curves: the long-run aggregate supply curve
LRAS and the short-run aggregate supply curve SRAS.We also need to discuss
how the economy makes the transition from the short run to the long run.
The Long Run: The Vertical Aggregate Supply Curve
Because the classical model describes how the economy behaves in the long
run, we derive the long-run aggregate supply curve from the classical model.
Recall from Chapter 3 that the amount of output produced depends on the
fixed amounts of capital and labor and on the available technology. To show
this, we write
Y = F(K
_
, L
_
)
= Y
_
.
According to the classical model, output does not depend on the price level.To
show that output is the same for all price levels, we draw a vertical aggregate
supply curve, as in Figure 9-4.The intersection of the aggregate demand curve
with this vertical aggregate supply curve determines the price level.
If the aggregate supply curve is vertical, then changes in aggregate demand af-
fect prices but not output. For example, if the money supply falls, the aggregate
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 245
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 246:27138#/eps at 100%*27138* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
demand curve shifts downward, as in Figure 9-5.The economy moves from the
old intersection of aggregate supply and aggregate demand, point A, to the new
intersection, point B.The shift in aggregate demand affects only prices.
The vertical aggregate supply curve satisfies the classical dichotomy, because it
implies that the level of output is independent of the money supply.This long-
run level of output, Y
–
, is called the full-employment or natural level of output. It is
the level of output at which the economy’s resources are fully employed or, more
realistically, at which unemployment is at its natural rate.
246 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 9-4
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
Long-run aggregate supply, LRAS
Y
The Long-Run Aggregate Supply
Curve In the long run, the level of
output is determined by the
amounts of capital and labor and
by the available technology; it
does not depend on the price
level. The long-run aggregate
supply curve, LRAS, is vertical.
figure 9-5
Price level, P
Income, output, YY
AD
1
AD
2
LRAS
A
B
1. A fall in aggregate
demand . . .
3. . . . but leaves
output the same.
2. . . . lowers
the price
level in the
long run . . .
Shifts in Aggregate Demand in
the Long Run A reduction in
the money supply shifts the
aggregate demand curve
downward from AD
1
to AD
2
.
The equilibrium for the
economy moves from point A
to point B. Since the aggregate
supply curve is vertical in the
long run, the reduction in
aggregate demand affects the
price level but not the level of
output.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 247:27139#/eps at 100%*27139* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
The Short Run: The Horizontal Aggregate Supply Curve
The classical model and the vertical aggregate supply curve apply only in the
long run. In the short run, some prices are sticky and, therefore, do not adjust to
changes in demand. Because of this price stickiness, the short-run aggregate sup-
ply curve is not vertical.
As an extreme example, suppose that all firms have issued price catalogs and
that it is costly for them to issue new ones.Thus, all prices are stuck at predeter-
mined levels.At these prices, firms are willing to sell as much as their customers
are willing to buy, and they hire just enough labor to produce the amount de-
manded. Because the price level is fixed, we represent this situation in Figure 9-6
with a horizontal aggregate supply curve.
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 247
figure 9-6
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
Short-run aggregate supply, SRAS
The Short-Run Aggregate Supply
Curve In this extreme example, all
prices are fixed in the short run.
Therefore, the short-run aggregate
supply curve, SRAS, is horizontal.
The short-run equilibrium of the economy is the intersection of the aggregate
demand curve and this horizontal short-run aggregate supply curve. In this case,
changes in aggregate demand do affect the level of output. For example, if the Fed
suddenly reduces the money supply, the aggregate demand curve shifts inward, as
in Figure 9-7. The economy moves from the old intersection of aggregate de-
mand and aggregate supply, point A, to the new intersection, point B.The move-
ment from point A to point B represents a decline in output at a fixed price level.
Thus, a fall in aggregate demand reduces output in the short run because
prices do not adjust instantly.After the sudden fall in aggregate demand, firms are
stuck with prices that are too high.With demand low and prices high, firms sell
less of their product, so they reduce production and lay off workers.The econ-
omy experiences a recession.
From the Short Run to the Long Run
We can summarize our analysis so far as follows: Over long periods of time, prices are
flexible, the aggregate supply curve is vertical, and changes in aggregate demand affect the price
level but not output. Over short periods of time, prices are sticky, the aggregate supply curve is
flat, and changes in aggregate demand do affect the economy’s output of goods and services.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 248:27140#/eps at 100%*27140* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
How does the economy make the transition from the short run to the long
run? Let’s trace the effects over time of a fall in aggregate demand. Suppose that
the economy is initially in long-run equilibrium, as shown in Figure 9-8. In this
figure, there are three curves: the aggregate demand curve, the long-run aggre-
gate supply curve, and the short-run aggregate supply curve.The long-run equi-
librium is the point at which aggregate demand crosses the long-run aggregate
supply curve. Prices have adjusted to reach this equilibrium.Therefore, when the
248 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 9-7
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
3. . . . lowers the
level of output.
2. . . . a fall in
aggregate
demand . . .
AD
1
AD
2
SRASAB
1. In the
short run
when prices
are sticky. . .
Shifts in Aggregate Demand in
the Short Run A reduction in the
money supply shifts the
aggregate demand curve
downward from AD
1
to AD
2
.
The equilibrium for the economy
moves from point A to point B.
Since the aggregate supply curve
is horizontal in the short run, the
reduction in aggregate demand
reduces the level of output.
figure 9-8
Price level, P
Income, output, Y
AD
Y
SRAS
LRAS
Long-run
equilibrium
Long-Run Equilibrium In the
long run, the economy finds itself
at the intersection of the long-
run aggregate supply curve and
the aggregate demand curve.
Because prices have adjusted to
this level, the short-run aggregate
supply curve crosses this point
as well.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 249:27141#/eps at 100%*27141* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
economy is in its long-run equilibrium, the short-run aggregate supply curve
must cross this point as well.
Now suppose that the Fed reduces the money supply and the aggregate de-
mand curve shifts downward, as in Figure 9-9. In the short run, prices are sticky,
so the economy moves from point A to point B. Output and employment fall
below their natural levels, which means the economy is in a recession. Over time,
in response to the low demand, wages and prices fall.The gradual reduction in
the price level moves the economy downward along the aggregate demand
curve to point C, which is the new long-run equilibrium. In the new long-run
equilibrium (point C), output and employment are back to their natural levels,
but prices are lower than in the old long-run equilibrium (point A).Thus, a shift
in aggregate demand affects output in the short run, but this effect dissipates over
time as firms adjust their prices.
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 249
figure 9-9
Price level, P
Income, output, YY
AD
1
AD
2
SRAS
LRAS
A
C
B
2. . . . lowers
output in
the short
run . . .
3. . . . but in the
long run affects
only the price level.
1. A fall in
aggregate
demand . . .
A Reduction in Aggregate
Demand The economy begins in
long-run equilibrium at point A.
A reduction in aggregate de-
mand, perhaps caused by a de-
crease in the money supply,
moves the economy from point
A to point B, where output is
below its natural level. As prices
fall, the economy gradually re-
covers from the recession, mov-
ing from point B to point C.
CASE STUDY
Gold, Greenbacks, and the Contraction of the 1870s
The aftermath of the Civil War in the United States provides a vivid example of
how contractionary monetary policy affects the economy. Before the war, the
United States was on a gold standard. Paper dollars were readily convertible into
gold. Under this policy, the quantity of gold determined the money supply and
the price level.
In 1862, after the Civil War broke out, the Treasury announced that it would
no longer redeem dollars for gold. In essence, this act replaced the gold standard
with a system of fiat money. Over the next few years, the government printed
large quantities of paper currency—called greenbacks for their color—and used
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 250:27142#/eps at 100%*27142* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
9-4 Stabilization Policy
Fluctuations in the economy as a whole come from changes in aggregate sup-
ply or aggregate demand. Economists call exogenous changes in these curves
shocks to the economy. A shock that shifts the aggregate demand curve is
called a demand shock, and a shock that shifts the aggregate supply curve is
called a supply shock.These shocks disrupt economic well-being by pushing
output and employment away from their natural rates. One goal of the model
of aggregate supply and aggregate demand is to show how shocks cause eco-
nomic fluctuations.
Another goal of the model is to evaluate how macroeconomic policy can re-
spond to these shocks. Economists use the term stabilization policy to refer to
policy actions aimed at reducing the severity of short-run economic fluctua-
tions. Because output and employment fluctuate around their long-run natural
rates, stabilization policy dampens the business cycle by keeping output and em-
ployment as close to their natural rates as possible.
In the coming chapters, we examine in detail how stabilization policy works
and what practical problems arise in its use. Here we begin our analysis of stabi-
lization policy by examining how monetary policy might respond to shocks.
Monetary policy is an important component of stabilization policy because, as
we have seen, the money supply has a powerful impact on aggregate demand.
Shocks to Aggregate Demand
Consider an example of a demand shock: the introduction and expanded avail-
ability of credit cards. Because credit cards are often a more convenient way to
make purchases than using cash, they reduce the quantity of money that people
choose to hold.This reduction in money demand is equivalent to an increase in
250 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
the seigniorage to finance wartime expenditure. Because of this increase in the
money supply, the price level approximately doubled during the war.
When the war was over, much political debate centered on the question of
whether to return to the gold standard.The Greenback party was formed with
the primary goal of maintaining the system of fiat money. Eventually, however,
the Greenback party lost the debate. Policymakers decided to retire the green-
backs over time in order to reinstate the gold standard at the rate of exchange be-
tween dollars and gold that had prevailed before the war.Their goal was to return
the value of the dollar to its former level.
Returning to the gold standard in this way required reversing the wartime rise
in prices, which meant aggregate demand had to fall. (To be more precise, the
growth in aggregate demand needed to fall short of the growth in the natural
rate of output.) As the price level fell, the economy experienced a recession from
1873 to 1879, the longest on record. By 1879, the price level was back to its level
before the war, and the gold standard was reinstated.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 251:27143#/eps at 100%*27143* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
the velocity of money.When each person holds less money, the money demand
parameter k falls.This means that each dollar of money moves from hand to hand
more quickly, so velocity V (= 1/k) rises.
If the money supply is held constant, the increase in velocity causes nominal
spending to rise and the aggregate demand curve to shift outward, as in Figure
9-10. In the short run, the increase in demand raises the output of the economy—
it causes an economic boom. At the old prices, firms now sell more output.
Therefore, they hire more workers, ask their existing workers to work longer
hours, and make greater use of their factories and equipment.
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 251
figure 9-10
Price level, P
Income, output, YY
AD
2
AD
1
SRAS
LRAS
A
C
B
2. . . . raises
output in
the short
run . . .
1. A rise in
aggregate
demand . . .
3. . . . but in the
long run affects
only the price level.
An Increase in Aggregate
Demand The economy begins in
long-run equilibrium at point A.
An increase in aggregate de-
mand, due to an increase in the
velocity of money, moves the
economy from point A to point
B, where output is above its nat-
ural level. As prices rise, output
gradually returns to its natural
rate, and the economy moves
from point B to point C.
Over time, the high level of aggregate demand pulls up wages and prices. As
the price level rises, the quantity of output demanded declines, and the economy
gradually approaches the natural rate of production. But during the transition to
the higher price level, the economy’s output is higher than the natural rate.
What can the Fed do to dampen this boom and keep output closer to the nat-
ural rate? The Fed might reduce the money supply to offset the increase in velocity.
Offsetting the change in velocity would stabilize aggregate demand.Thus, the Fed
can reduce or even eliminate the impact of demand shocks on output and employ-
ment if it can skillfully control the money supply.Whether the Fed in fact has the
necessary skill is a more difficult question, which we take up in Chapter 14.
Shocks to Aggregate Supply
Shocks to aggregate supply, as well as shocks to aggregate demand, can cause eco-
nomic fluctuations.A supply shock is a shock to the economy that alters the cost
of producing goods and services and, as a result, the prices that firms charge.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 252:27144#/eps at 100%*27144* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
Because supply shocks have a direct impact on the price level, they are some-
times called price shocks. Here are some examples:
? A drought that destroys crops.The reduction in food supply pushes up
food prices.
? A new environmental protection law that requires firms to reduce their
emissions of pollutants. Firms pass on the added costs to customers in the
form of higher prices.
? An increase in union aggressiveness.This pushes up wages and the prices
of the goods produced by union workers.
? The organization of an international oil cartel. By curtailing competition,
the major oil producers can raise the world price of oil.
All these events are adverse supply shocks, which means they push costs and prices
upward.A favorable supply shock, such as the breakup of an international oil car-
tel, reduces costs and prices.
Figure 9-11 shows how an adverse supply shock affects the economy. The
short-run aggregate supply curve shifts upward. (The supply shock may also lower
the natural level of output and thus shift the long-run aggregate supply curve to
the left, but we ignore that effect here.) If aggregate demand is held constant, the
economy moves from point A to point B: the price level rises and the amount of
output falls below the natural rate.An experience like this is called stagflation, be-
cause it combines stagnation (falling output) with inflation (rising prices).
Faced with an adverse supply shock, a policymaker controlling aggregate
demand, such as the Fed, has a difficult choice between two options.The first
option, implicit in Figure 9-11, is to hold aggregate demand constant. In this
case, output and employment are lower than the natural rate. Eventually, prices
252 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
figure 9-11
Price level, P
Income, output, YY
AD
SRAS
1
LRAS
A
B
SRAS
2
3. . . . and
output to fall.
1. An adverse supply
shock shifts the short-
run aggregate supply
curve upward, . . .
2. . . . which
causes the
price level
to rise . . .
An Adverse Supply Shock An ad-
verse supply shock pushes up costs
and thus prices. If aggregate de-
mand is held constant, the econ-
omy moves from point A to point B,
leading to stagflation—a combina-
tion of increasing prices and falling
output. Eventually, as prices fall, the
economy returns to the natural
rate, point A.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 253:27145#/eps at 100%*27145* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
will fall to restore full employment at the old price level (point A). But the cost
of this adjustment process is a painful recession.
The second option, illustrated in Figure 9-12, is to expand aggregate demand
to bring the economy toward the natural rate more quickly. If the increase in ag-
gregate demand coincides with the shock to aggregate supply, the economy goes
immediately from point A to point C. In this case, the Fed is said to accommodate
the supply shock.The drawback of this option, of course, is that the price level is
permanently higher.There is no way to adjust aggregate demand to maintain full
employment and keep the price level stable.
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 253
figure 9-12
Price level, P
Income, output, YY
AD
1
AD
2
SRAS
1
LRAS
A
C
SRAS
2
3. . . .
resulting
in a
permanently
higher price
level . . .
2. . . . but the Fed accommodates
the shock by raising aggregate
demand, . . .
4. . . . but
no change
in output.
1. An adverse supply
shock shifts the short-
run aggregate supply
curve upward . . .
Accommodating an Adverse
Supply Shock In response to
an adverse supply shock, the
Fed can increase aggregate de-
mand to prevent a reduction in
output. The economy moves
from point A to point C. The
cost of this policy is a perma-
nently higher level of prices.
CASE STUDY
How OPEC Helped Cause Stagflation in the 1970s and Euphoria in
the 1980s
The most disruptive supply shocks in recent history were caused by OPEC, the
Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries. In the early 1970s, OPEC’s co-
ordinated reduction in the supply of oil nearly doubled the world price.This in-
crease in oil prices caused stagflation in most industrial countries.These statistics
show what happened in the United States:
Change in Inflation Unemployment
Year Oil Prices Rate (CPI) Rate
1973 11.0% 6.2% 4.9%
1974 68.0 11.0 5.6
1975 16.0 9.1 8.5
1976 3.3 5.8 7.7
1977 8.1 6.5 7.1
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 254:27146#/eps at 100%*27146* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
254 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
The 68-percent increase in the price of oil in 1974 was an adverse supply shock
of major proportions.As one would have expected, it led to both higher inflation
and higher unemployment.
A few years later, when the world economy had nearly recovered from the
first OPEC recession, almost the same thing happened again. OPEC raised oil
prices, causing further stagflation. Here are the statistics for the United States:
Change in Inflation Unemployment
Year Oil Prices Rate (CPI) Rate
1978 9.4% 7.7% 6.1%
1979 25.4 11.3 5.8
1980 47.8 13.5 7.0
1981 44.4 10.3 7.5
1982 ?8.7 6.1 9.5
The increases in oil prices in 1979, 1980, and 1981 again led to double-digit in-
flation and higher unemployment.
In the mid-1980s, political turmoil among the Arab countries weakened
OPEC’s ability to restrain supplies of oil. Oil prices fell, reversing the stagflation
of the 1970s and the early 1980s. Here’s what happened:
Change in Inflation Unemployment
Year Oil Prices Rate (CPI) Rate
1983 ?7.1% 3.2% 9.5%
1984 ?1.7 4.3 7.4
1985 ?7.5 3.6 7.1
1986 ?44.5 1.9 6.9
1987 l8.3 3.6 6.1
In 1986 oil prices fell by nearly half.This favorable supply shock led to one of
the lowest inflation rates experienced in recent U.S. history and to falling un-
employment.
More recently, OPEC has not been a major cause of economic fluctuations.
This is in part because OPEC has been less successful at raising the price of oil.
Although world oil prices have fluctuated, the changes have not been as large as
those experienced during the 1970s, and the real price of oil has never returned
to the peaks reached in the early 1980s. Moreover, conservation efforts and tech-
nological changes have made the economy less susceptible to oil shocks. The
amount of oil consumed per unit of real GDP has fallen about 40 percent over
the past three decades.
But we should not be too sanguine.The experiences of the 1970s and 1980s
could always be repeated. Events in the Middle East are a potential source of
shocks to economies around the world.
3
3
Some economists have suggested that changes in oil prices played a major role in economic fluc-
tuations even before the 1970s. See James D. Hamilton,“Oil and the Macroeconomy Since World
War II,’’ Journal of Political Economy 91 (April 1983): 228–248.
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 255:27147#/eps at 100%*27147* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
9-5 Conclusion
This chapter introduced a framework to study economic fluctuations: the model
of aggregate supply and aggregate demand.The model is built on the assumption
that prices are sticky in the short run and flexible in the long run. It shows how
shocks to the economy cause output to deviate temporarily from the level im-
plied by the classical model.
The model also highlights the role of monetary policy. Poor monetary policy
can be a source of shocks to the economy. A well-run monetary policy can re-
spond to shocks and stabilize the economy.
In the chapters that follow, we refine our understanding of this model and our
analysis of stabilization policy. Chapters 10 through 12 go beyond the quantity
equation to refine our theory of aggregate demand.This refinement shows that
aggregate demand depends on fiscal policy as well as monetary policy. Chapter
13 examines aggregate supply in more detail. Chapter 14 examines the debate
over the virtues and limits of stabilization policy.
Summary
1. The crucial difference between the long run and the short run is that prices
are flexible in the long run but sticky in the short run.The model of aggre-
gate supply and aggregate demand provides a framework to analyze eco-
nomic fluctuations and see how the impact of policies varies over different
time horizons.
2. The aggregate demand curve slopes downward. It tells us that the lower the
price level, the greater the aggregate quantity of goods and services de-
manded.
3. In the long run, the aggregate supply curve is vertical because output is deter-
mined by the amounts of capital and labor and by the available technology,
but not by the level of prices.Therefore, shifts in aggregate demand affect the
price level but not output or employment.
4. In the short run, the aggregate supply curve is horizontal, because wages and
prices are sticky at predetermined levels. Therefore, shifts in aggregate de-
mand affect output and employment.
5. Shocks to aggregate demand and aggregate supply cause economic fluctua-
tions. Because the Fed can shift the aggregate demand curve, it can attempt to
offset these shocks to maintain output and employment at their natural rates.
CHAPTER 9 Introduction to Economic Fluctuations | 255
KEY CONCEPTS
Aggregate demand
Aggregate supply
Shocks
Demand shocks
Supply shocks
Stabilization policy
User JOEWA:Job EFF01425:6264_ch09:Pg 256:27148#/eps at 100%*27148* Wed, Feb 13, 2002 10:08 AM
256 | PART IV Business Cycle Theory: The Economy in the Short Run
1. Give an example of a price that is sticky in the
short run and flexible in the long run.
2. Why does the aggregate demand curve slope
downward?
QUESTIONS FOR REVIEW
3. Explain the impact of an increase in the money
supply in the short run and in the long run.
4. Why is it easier for the Fed to deal with demand
shocks than with supply shocks?
PROBLEMS AND APPLICATIONS
1. Suppose that a change in government regulations
allows banks to start paying interest on checking
accounts. Recall that the money stock is the sum
of currency and demand deposits, including
checking accounts, so this regulatory change
makes holding money more attractive.
a. How does this change affect the demand for
money?
b. What happens to the velocity of money?
c. If the Fed keeps the money supply constant,
what will happen to output and prices in the
short run and in the long run?
d. Should the Fed keep the money supply con-
stant in response to this regulatory change?
Why or why not?
2. Suppose the Fed reduces the money supply by 5
percent.
a. What happens to the aggregate demand curve?
b. What happens to the level of output and the
price level in the short run and in the long
run?
c. According to Okun’s law, what happens to un-
employment in the short run and in the long
run? (Hint: Okun’s law is the relationship be-
tween output and unemployment discussed in
Chapter 2.)
d. What happens to the real interest rate in the
short run and in the long run? (Hint: Use the
model of the real interest rate in Chapter 3 to
see what happens when output changes.)
3. Let’s examine how the goals of the Fed influence
its response to shocks. Suppose Fed A cares only
about keeping the price level stable, and Fed B
cares only about keeping output and employment
at their natural rates. Explain how each Fed
would respond to
a. An exogenous decrease in the velocity of
money.
b. An exogenous increase in the price of oil.
4. The official arbiter of when recessions begin and
end is the National Bureau of Economic Re-
search, a nonprofit economics research group. Go
to the NBER’s Web site (www.nber.org) and find
the latest turning point in the business cycle.
When did it occur? Was this a switch from expan-
sion to contraction or the other way around? List
all the recessions (contractions) that have oc-
curred during your lifetime and the dates when
they began and ended.